Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:J-a:Journal Of Business Research:Vol50.Issue2.2000:

Alternative Profitability Measures and Marketing
Channel Structure: The Franchise Decision
Patrick J. Kaufmann
BOSTON UNIVERSITY

Richard M. Gordon
UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA

James E. Owers
GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY

Analysis of marketing channel structure in general, and the decision to
franchise in particular, has assumed that the decision maker is seeking
to maximize the long-term economic value of the firm. In this article, we
consider an alternative accounting-based objective function. We explore
some circumstances that might lead to the use of an accounting-based
objective function, including the incentive structure faced by non-owner
managers, the life cycle of the firm including an impending initial public
offering, and data availability considerations. A simple model of franchisor
performance is developed and several scenarios of franchise system expansion examined. Decisions to open franchised or company-owned outlets
are compared using the competing objective functions. J BUSN RES 2000.

50.217–224.  2000 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved.

O

ne of the most important methods of distribution in
the United States is franchising. Because it provides
a quasi-integrated alternative to markets or hierarchies, it raises interesting questions involving marketing channel structure decisions. The most central and unresolved question is “What factors influence a retailer to distribute its products
or services through company-owned vs. franchised units?”
While this question can be examined using a variety of
approaches (e.g., behavioral, economic/financial, or managerial), most of the research addressing the question has been
conducted within an economic/financial framework (Rubin,
1978). The economic/financial framework assumes that business firms seek to maximize their long-run profits and wealth
(Koutsoyiannis, 1982), using performance measures that focus
on the firm’s economic value (EV).
This assumption is critical because of the influence that
Address correspondence to Patrick J. Kaufmann, Marketing Department,
School of Management, Boston University, 595 Commonwealth Ave., Boston,
MA 02215. E-mail: patk@bu.edu.
Journal of Business Research 50, 217–224 (2000)
 2000 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved.

655 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10010

the choice of performance measures has on financial structure,
and the influence that financial structure has on the scope of
a business enterprise (Li and Li, 1996). Theoretically, markets
value a firm with reference to long-term economic profit, and
economic value and financial market value should be one and
the same. Although we do not contest the fact that in the long
run the market will reflect economic value, we suggest that
there may be circumstances in the short run that lead the
market (and firm management) to attend to accounting measures of performance (AV measures). In doing so, we show
how a franchisor’s choice of EV or AV measures is related to
its decisions concerning the mix of franchised and companyowned outlets. The choice of financial measures, therefore, is
closely linked to a marketing decision: the design of the firm’s
distribution channel.
In subsequent sections, we also examine the implications
of the finance–marketing link with respect to an important
sub-issue: the strategic conversion of franchised to companyowned channels (i.e., ownership redirection). We develop a
simple model of franchise system economics and simulate the
expansion of the system under various scenarios. The model

shows the choices of an optimal mix of franchised and company-owned outlets may turn on whether a firm uses EV or
AV measures. We end by discussing the importance of these
findings to the ownership redirection issue.

Comparison of AV and EV Measures
AV measures, such as net income (NI) and earnings per share
(EPS), are calculated using Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles (GAAP). GAAP “encompasses the conventions, rules,
and procedures necessary to define accepted accounting practice
at a particular time” (AICPA, 1995, p. 485).
In a franchising firm with a simple capital structure, NI
ISSN 0148-2963/00/$–see front matter
PII S0148-2963(99)00035-1

218

J Busn Res
2000:50:217–224

is calculated by deducting ordinary expenses from ordinary

income. Ordinary expenses include the costs related to the
selling of franchises (e.g., recruiting franchisees), of servicing
(i.e., monitoring) franchised units, and of operating and servicing company units. EPS is calculated by dividing NI by the
number of shares of stock outstanding.
In contrast, EV measures, such as net operating profit after
tax (NOPAT) and r (the operating return on assets), are calculated by making adjustments to their AV counterparts (NI
and EPS). There are numerous residual income or EV-based
measures of firm performance. We use a simplified version
of the most familiar measure Economic Value Added or EVAw
(Stewart, 1991), noting that there are over 160 versions of
that particular measure (Myers, 1996). EVA relates NOPAT
to capital employed as follows: EVA 5 [(NOPAT/Capital) 2
Cost of Capital] 3 Capital. The component (NOPAT/Capital)
is the EV performance measure and must exceed the cost of
capital to add value to the firm. In our model, we assume the
proportion of debt to equity (i.e., the capital structure) to be
invariant with respect to the franchising decision. Thus, the
cost of capital is not affected by that decision, and our EV
analysis focuses solely on the NOPAT/Capital component.
In a firm with a simple capital structure, NOPAT starts

with NI, and adds back two categories of expenses that were
deducted in calculating NI: (1) expenses paid to providers of
capital other than holders of common stock, and (2) expenses
deemed to lack “economic reality” with respect to company
valuation. The purpose of the first category of add backs is
to reflect the firm’s total operating return. In a firm that incurs
debt, these add backs include interest expense after tax. The
second category of add backs is made because GAAP conventions represent compromises between reporting the operating
economics of the firm and reporting information that is usable
for other purposes (e.g., for decisions about extending credit).
The EV measure, r, therefore, is calculated by dividing NOPAT
by total invested capital (not just equity capital, as in EPS)
(see Table 1).
Although the EV measure, r, and the AV measure, EPS, differ
both with respect to their numerators (the income-derived
term of the measures) and with respect to their denominators
(the capital-base-derived term), it is the difference in their
denominators that has the greatest impact on the decision to
favor either franchised or company-owned outlets. The effect
of the differences in the denominators is that franchisors who

use AV measures may favor asset accumulation (companyowned outlets) in circumstances in which EV measures, which
focus on asset efficiency, may discourage asset accumulation
(and thereby favor franchised units).

Economic and Alternative
Assumptions in Franchising Research
From the outset, the assumption that franchisors pursue an
economic value maximizing approach (using EV measures)

P. J. Kaufmann et al.

has been the foundation of most of the research concerning
franchising (Rubin, 1978). As March (1962, p. 670) has noted,
however, “modern observers of actual firm behavior report
persistent and significant contradictions between firm behavior and the classical assumptions” (i.e., the assumptions of
profit or utility maximization). Consequently, some researchers have considered other goals for franchisors, such as growth
(Kaufmann and Dant, 1996), survival (Shane, 1996), and
power and control, for example, the greater ability to control
strategic input from franchisees as compared with heavily
invested venture capitalists (Lafontaine and Kaufmann, 1994).

Nevertheless, because relatively few researchers have applied
non-economic approaches directly to the questions of franchise
ownership structure and ownership redirection, the standard
economic assumption has dominated research in this area.
We contend that the assumption that franchisors invariably
seek to maximize economic value is too strong and may lead
to a misinterpretation of observed choices with respect to the
ownership of units. We are not suggesting that franchisors
act irrationally. We do suggest that there are circumstances
in which a franchisor may be guided directly by AV measures
or by an alternative objective function that involves the use
of AV measures. Empirical evidence suggests that improving
a firm’s performance on AV measures has been an important
goal for many senior executives in the United States. In fact,
Jensen (1989) suggests that one of the critical problems with
the public corporation is that managers traditionally seek to
maximize earnings (an AV measure) instead of value.

Size-Based Managerial Compensation
One driving force behind a franchisor’s focus on AV measures

may be executive compensation. The connection between increases in executive pay and increases in firm size has been
consistently demonstrated (Murphy, 1985). Thus, senior managers of publicly held franchise companies may favor building
the company’s asset base by increasing the proportion of company-owned units, even if a lower proportion would maximize
EV measures of performance. On the other hand, if firms
move toward the use of compensation plans based on residual
income or firm value, the importance of AV measures to top
management would diminish (Wallace, 1996).

Data Availability
It is quite difficult for inside management to compile the data
necessary to create accurate EV measures (Myers, 1996); it is
even more difficult for outside investors to get independent
access to the data necessary to construct the measures [although some proprietary measures are available for purchase,
see Biddle, Bowen, and Wallace (1996)]. EV adjustments,
such as the valuation for goodwill amortization and changes
in reserves, often are too idiosyncratic to permit efficient comparisons across firms. On the other hand, AV data concerning
franchisors and public companies are readily available, and

Franchise System Economics


J Busn Res
2000:50:217–224

219

Table 1. Comparison of AV and EV Metrics

Income Measure
(Numerator)

AV

EV

Informational Content

Net income (after tax)
(NI)

Net operating profit

after tax (NOPAT)

AV measures net income after interest is deducted.
EV measures operating profit before interest is
deducted.
AV and EV are both after tax measures.

Standardized by
(Denominator)

Number of shares
(none when NI is
used alone)

Invested capital

Primary AV measure becomes EPS, primary EV
measure is r, operating return on capital (or
assets).
AV evaluates operations and financing together. EV

separates efficiency of operations (r) from financing
decisions.

Units of Measure

EPS is $

r is %

The EV metric (r) is compared to the cost of capital.
The aggregate $ EV is calculated after scaling by
capital employed.

Interpretation of
Measure

Absolute size

Relative efficiency

AV requires a benchmark to judge efficiency. EV
relates to a direct efficiency benchmark—the cost of
capital. The cost of capital should be minimized by
the astute use of leverage in the financing decisions.

investors are accustomed to analyzing data in AV form, a
process explicitly facilitated by the use of GAAP guidelines.
Even if EV measures have become more popular for internal
management purposes, AV measures remain important measures for investors. Thus, franchisors who wish to attract or
maintain the interest of investors are likely to attend to AV
measures. In addition, investors’ assessments of firm value are
based not just on the present value of cash flows from assets
in place, but also on the present value of growth opportunities.
When the growth opportunities component of firm value
dominates, the estimation of EV measures is much more difficult, and AV measures are more likely to be used to assess
the firm’s value.

Other Firm Life-Cycle Considerations
Many franchisors began as small retail entrepreneurs, and
have used franchising to expand their business far beyond
their initial dreams and aspirations. In some cases, the business
sophistication of those franchisors lags their expansion success, and the use of more familiar AV measures continues even
when the system should have outgrown the initial naivete. In
a franchise system’s life cycle, therefore, AV measures may
dominate until the firm moves from its initial entrepreneurial
orientation to become a more professionally run company.
Even sophisticated franchisors who are contemplating an
initial public offering of their equity (an IPO) may be driven
to favor AV measures. Investment bankers commonly advise
companies to build both NI and assets in anticipation of an
IPO (Continental Franchise Review, 1995). To fully benefit
from an IPO, a company must be large enough in terms of
revenue and earnings to attract institutional investors and be
followed by industry analysts. Common target levels of revenue and net income are $20 million and $1 million (Blowers,

Ericksen, and Milan, 1995). It is interesting to note that franchise companies often emphasize total system sales from both
franchised and company-owned outlets when speaking to the
press even though the franchisor’s revenue may only be a
small portion of those sales.
The importance of AV performance to the success of an
IPO leads many investment bankers to advise franchisors to
open more company-owned units and to buy back existing
franchised units, even if the units must be reacquired at higher
prices than would be justified using EV measures. Opening
company-owned units or buying back previously franchised
units may depress EV measures (because of the increase in
the investment base—the denominator of r), but it increases
the franchisor’s current and expected NI and EPS, as well as
its asset base. (Pure franchising companies often have relatively
few assets other than their franchise contracts, which typically
are not valued by investors as highly as the bricks and mortar
of company-owned units.)
After an IPO is completed, management still may have good
reason to use AV measures. Although there is some disagreement (see Stewart, 1991), EPS still appears to be the market’s
pre-eminent measure of firm performance. EPS “commands
more interest and is more instrumental in determining market
price” of a stock than any other measure (Sharp, 1986, p. 38).
“The strongest influence on stock prices is investor expectations
of a company’s future earnings” (Klott, 1987, p. 179).
Academic studies find a close, long-term correspondence
between earnings and stock prices (Elton and Gruber, 1995;
Fischer and Jordan, 1995). The relationship is not merely
statistical, but has a “strong base in the theory of investment
value” (Harrington, Fabozzi, and Fogler, 1990, p. 137). Although he decries it, Rappaport (1986, p. 19) agrees that “there
is an obsessive fixation on earnings per share as the scorecard

220

J Busn Res
2000:50:217–224

of corporate performance.” Finally, in a direct test of the relative
information content in EV and AV measures, Biddle, Bowen, and
Wallace (1996) find no evidence to suggest that EV measures
outperform AV measures in predicting stock prices.
The positive impact of increasing the proportion of company-owned outlets on stock price was demonstrated by Brickley, Dark, and Weisbach (1991). They posited that the stock
price increase was the market’s response to changing monitoring costs (i.e., the franchisor’s decision to increase the proportion of company outlets signals that the franchisor’s cost of
monitoring outlets has decreased). However, the stock price
increase also is consistent with a market response to the positive changes in AV measures that result from the higher proportion of company outlets.

A Simple Model of Franchisor
Results Using EV and AV Measures
As suggested above, for a variety of reasons including the anticipation of an IPO, franchisors may focus on AV measures. The
impact of this focus is to lead them to acquire franchised outlets
or to shift to opening company units. To demonstrate this effect,
we use a simple algebraic model of franchise economics.

Description of Model
The model transforms input assumptions into two sets of
measures of franchise system value: AV measures and EV
measures. The AV measures are based on growth in NI. The
EV measure, r, is a measure of the return on capital employed
(see Appendix A). Two potential revenue streams a franchisor
may receive are included in the calculations: revenue from
franchising, and revenue from company-owned units. We vary
the number of franchised and company-owned units added
to the system each year to reflect three alternative expansion
strategies (all units company-owned, all units franchised, and
a mix of both), and examine the results in terms of the AV
and EV measures. We also examine measures of firm size
under each expansion strategy.
The model uses the following input variables and assumed
values:
1. Initial franchise fee 5 $20K
2. Ongoing royalty rate 5 6% of gross sales
3. Average volume of a franchised unit 5 $300K per
period
4. Franchisor’s cost to service (monitor) each franchise
unit 5 $10K per period
5. Franchisor’s cost to sell a franchise 5 Initial franchise
fee
6. Average volume of a company-owned unit 5 Average
volume of a franchised unit
7. Average operating expense ratio of company-owned
units 5 75%
8. Franchisor’s cost to service (monitor) each company-

P. J. Kaufmann et al.

9.
10.

11.
12.
13.
14.

owned unit 5 3X the Franchisor’s cost to service (monitor) each franchised unit
Each franchised unit requires the franchisor to make
a one-time infrastructure investment of $2K
Each company unit requires the franchisor to make a
one-time infrastructure investment 5 2X the one-time
infrastructure investment required for each franchised
unit
It requires an investment of $150K to open a unit
Franchisor borrows 50% of the investment needed to
open a unit
The interest rate on franchisor borrowing is 8.0%
The franchisor incurs a total effective tax rate of 50%

Using these assumptions, the model returns plausible results that are consistent with published analyses. For example,
the assumptions produce earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization (EBITDA) with respect to franchise royalties of 44%. In two separate analyses of franchise
system earnings, SohlenRosenfeld Capital used EBITDA values
of 25% (Continental Franchise Review, 1995) and “40 percent
plus” (Continental Franchise Review, 1996). Thus, the assumptions provide reasonable results with respect to the first
revenue stream: revenue from franchising. In fact, the model’s
assumptions produce results on the high end for franchise
revenue. This suggests that if bias exists in the model’s AV
measures, it would act to reduce the preference for companyowned units over franchised units. The assumptions also produce unit-level EBITDA margins of 15% for company-owned
units. This figure equals the margins used by SohlenRosenfeld
Capital (Continental Franchise Review, 1995) and supports
the reasonableness of the assumptions with respect to the
second revenue stream: revenue from company-owned units.
We calculate three AV measures of firm size and two AV
measures of profitability. The three measures of firm size are:
(1) total revenue in year 10, (2) NI in year 10, and (3) total
capitalization in year 10.
The AV measures of profitability are based on the growth
of NI over the 10-year period. For tractability purposes we
have assumed a simple equity structure (i.e., a structure with
common stock only), and have assumed that the number of
shares remain constant. The effect of these assumptions is
that growth of NI is equivalent to growth of EPS. The NI
growth rate is measured as (1) the average growth rate over
the 10-year period, and (2) the compounded growth rate for
the 10-year period. The EV output measure is the average r
over the 10-year period.

Findings and Interpretations
Firm Size
A firm’s management will favor a company-owned development strategy if it perceives compensation or IPO benefits to
be related to AV measures of firm size (see Table 2).

Franchise System Economics

J Busn Res
2000:50:217–224

221

Table 2. AV Measures of Firm Sizea

Franchising
Company-owned
a

Revenue
in Year 10

NI
in Year 10

Total Capitalization
in Year 10

$7,640
$114,000

$1,520
$5,985

$1,000
$61,800

Adding 40 units per year for 10 years, all franchised or all company-owned; all figures in 000s.

Firm Profitability
Using the same two scenarios as in Table 2, we use the model
to calculate AV and EV profitability figures over the 10-year
period. Table 3 shows the resulting AV-measures (average and
compound growth rate of NI) and the resulting EV measure, r,
under each scenario.
If the firm must choose a pure strategy and uses EV measures, it will franchise its units because the r achieved is greater
than if it owns the units. The AV profitability measures do
not favor either pure strategy, so the firm will make its decision
using other criteria (perhaps including a size criterion which
will favor company ownership, as shown in Table 2).
Next, we use the model to simulate a familiar scenario: a
franchisor which has franchised in its earlier years, and now
must decide whether to continue franchising. This decision
may become salient because the franchisor is considering an
IPO or because the franchisor now believes (perhaps mistakenly) that capital is more available to it, and it doesn’t “need”
to franchise (Oxenfeldt and Kelly, 1968).
We assume the franchisor franchises for five years and then
either (1) continues franchising during years 6–15, or (2)
switches to company-owned units. Table 4 shows the AV and
EV-measure results for the 10 years after the decision is made
(i.e., for years 6–15).
If the firm uses EV measures, it will continue to franchise
because the r achieved is greater than if it switches to a
company-owned strategy. If the firm used AV measures, the
profitability results are better if it does switch to companyowned outlets. AV measures of firm size in year 15 also favor
switching to company-owned units.
The phenomena portrayed in Table 4 do not depend on
the particular year in which the switch is made and are not
sensitive to reasonable changes in the model’s assumptions.
(As a whole, the assumptions favor franchising.)
The effect of making a switch from franchised to company

units is consistent, even if the switch involves a mixed ownership scenario. In the pure scenario described above, the firm
switches from all franchised units (40 per year) to all companyowned units (also 40 per year). In the mixed scenario, the
firm opens 30 franchised units and 10 company units per
year over the first five years, and then must decide whether
to maintain or alter that mix. The firm may continue to favor
franchised units (30 per year) over company units (10 per
year) or may switch to a strategy that favors company units
(30 per year) over franchised units (10 per year). Table 5
shows the AV- and EV-measure results for the 10 years after
the decision is made.
Consistent with the analysis of the pure strategies, if the
firm uses EV measures, it will continue to franchise most of
its units and will not increase the proportion of companyowned units. If the firm uses AV measures, it has strong
incentives to increase the proportion of company-owned units.

Discussion and Implications
for Related Research
Oxenfeldt and Kelly (1968) posited that franchisors franchise
begrudgingly, and only do so in order to attract capital for
the initial expansion of their operation. Franchisees are hard
to control, so when franchisors no longer face human and
financial capital constraints, they will buy back the franchises
and operate all but the marginal outlets as company stores.
At the core of Oxenfeldt and Kelly’s idea was the accepted
belief that capital could be more efficiently acquired by selling
franchised outlets than by selling shares in a company chain.
This thesis set in motion a series of theoretical and empirical
papers that sought to prove or disprove their basic contention
[see Dant, Paswan, and Kaufmann (1996) for a meta-analysis
of the relevant research].
Rubin (1978) attacked their basic assumption and argued

Table 3. EV and AV Measures of Profitabilitya

Franchising
Company-owned
a

NI Average
Growth
Rate
Years 1–10

NI
Compounded
Average Growth
Rate Years 1–10

r
Average
Years 1–10

0.46
0.46

0.39
0.39

1.12
0.10

Adding 40 units per year for 10 years, all franchised or all company-owned.

222

J Busn Res
2000:50:217–224

P. J. Kaufmann et al.

Table 4. EV and AV Measures with Complete Change in Strategya

Continue franchising
Switch to
company-owned
a

NI Average
Growth Rate
Years 6–15

NI
Compounded
Average Growth
Rate Years 6–15

r
Average
Years 6–15

0.11

0.11

1.51

0.23

0.22

0.14

Adding 40 franchised units per year for five years, then continuing or changing strategy for the next 10 years.

that if capital markets are efficient, then the greater diversification offered to investors in a chain of stores (and the commensurate reduction in risk) would make the sale of shares less
costly than capital provided by franchisees (because franchisees bear the undiversified risk of owning only one store).
Consequently, Rubin argued, the rationale for franchising
must lie elsewhere: in the incentives created by the franchisees’
claims to profits and the bonding effect of the franchise fee.
Lafontaine (1992) responded that if Rubin’s incentive arguments were correct, then investors would be aware of the
motivation and monitoring problems faced by a company
using employee store managers. This would cause investors
to demand higher returns on their share holdings, which could
make franchisee-provided capital relatively more efficient after
all. Thus, the need to finance expansion remains a possible
rationale for franchising (Kaufmann and Dant, 1996).
The question of whether franchising reflects a preferred
method of financing expansion or the solution to agency problems takes on a different meaning if we change the basic
assumptions about the objective function of the franchisor.
As shown above, if a franchisor is seeking to maximize AV,
it will benefit more from capital invested in company units
than from capital invested in supporting franchising, even
though the capital invested in company units may be less
efficient according to EV measures than capital invested in

franchising. Company outlets deliver more NI than franchise
royalties deliver, and AV measures are driven by NI. Therefore,
all else being equal, a franchisor maximizing AV will favor
company outlets and will franchise only if it must (i.e., only
if it has no access to capital other than from franchisees).
To this point, we have focused on the efficiency of capital.
What is the impact of considering agency issues? Franchisees
are assumed to be less likely to shirk and thus deliver greater
store level returns than employee managers. An AV maximizing retailer will franchise an outlet if, and only if, store managers shirk so severely that the operating profits from a company
outlet are less than the net royalties (i.e., royalties minus
the operating expenses of running the franchise system) the
franchisor would receive from the outlet in the hands of a
franchisee. Because royalties are typically a relatively small
percentage of sales, this rarely occurs. Therefore, for AVmaximizing retailers, franchising is more likely to reflect the
lack of an alternative source of capital than an attempt to
solve agency problems.
On the other hand, for EV maximizing retailers, the cost of
the capital tied up in company-owned outlets is charged against
NI, and the franchising becomes more attractive even when
sufficient capital is available to open company-owned units.
Our analysis has significant implications with respect to
Oxenfeldt and Kelly’s thesis. Retailers who manage their busi-

Table 5. EV and AV Measures with Partial Change in Strategya
NI Average
Growth Rate
Years 6–15

NI
Compounded
Average Growth
Rate Years 6–15

r
Average
Years 6–15

All 40 franchised,
year 6 switch to
franchising 30 and
opening 10
company-owned

0.11

0.11

0.18

All 40 companyowned, year 6
switch to opening
30 company-owned
and franchising 10

0.16

0.16

0.14

a

Adding 40 franchised or company-owned units per year for five years, then changing to a mixed strategy for the next 10 years.

Franchise System Economics

J Busn Res
2000:50:217–224

223

ness so as to maximize AV instead of EV will be more likely
to favor owning company units, and vice versa. Consequently,
if a franchisor shifts from EV to AV objectives (for example, in
anticipation of an IPO), one would expect to see the franchisor
move toward the greater proportion of company-owned outlets predicted by Oxenfeldt and Kelly, but for an entirely
different reason than the one they proposed.
On the other hand, if a franchisor shifts from AV to EV
measures, it is likely to franchise a greater proportion of its
outlets. This shift is contrary to Oxenfeldt and Kelly’s hypothesized life-cycle tendency toward company-owned outlets, and
may explain some of the contradictory empirical results in
this area (Dant, Paswan, and Kaufmann, 1996).
We have discussed the reasons a firm may shift from EV
to AV measures. Shifts in the other direction also are occurring.
EV measures are being marketed aggressively by consulting
firms, including Stern Stewart & Co., HOLT Value Associates,
and the Boston Consulting Group. At the same time, large
U.S. companies are developing their own EV measures inhouse (Myers, 1996). A number of public companies have
shifted from AV to EV measures. For example, lamenting the
amount of capital required to open company-owned restaurants, the chairman of Pepsico told analysts that by leveraging
its funds to open more franchised outlets, Pepsico subsidiary
Pizza Hut could double its “free” cash generation (Rudnitsky,
1995). A shift to a more EV-focused strategy may be one
explanation for Pepsico’s abrupt reversal from a clear strategy
of reacquiring franchises in the late 1980s to a program of
selling company-owned outlets to franchisees (PRNewswire,
Sept. 26, 1996). It is also consistent with the recent decision
to spin off the entire restaurant group.
Our model and analysis have a narrow focus. We have
considered the influence of the choice of EV versus AV financial measures on firm structure in only one context: the marketing channel decision to franchise. Most of our consideration
of the decision to franchise falls within one framework: a
framework of economic rationality. Our analysis may be limited to franchisors who are sophisticated enough to understand and attend to the differences between EV and AV approaches. Nevertheless, because of the demonstrated impact
of a shift in orientation from EV to AV measures or vice versa
and because of the evidence that these shifts do occur, we
believe it is important for researchers to identify firm-specific
objectives and to incorporate them in the analysis of the
decision to use franchised or direct channels.

Biddle, Gary C., Bowen, Robert M., and Wallace, James S.: Evidence on
the Relative and Incremental Information Content of EVAw, Residual
Income, Earnings and Operating Cash Flow, University of Washington Working Paper, 1996.

References

PRNewswire: Pepsico, Inc. Announces Strategic Action, Sept. 26, 1996.

AICPA: AICPA Professional Standards, Volume 1, American Institute
of Certified Public Accountants, New York, NY. 1995.

Rappaport, Alfred: Creating Shareholder Value, Free Press, New York,
NY. 1986.

Blowers, Stephen C., Ericksen, Gregory K., and Milan, Thomas L.:
The Ernst & Young Guide to Taking Your Company Public, John
Wiley & Sons, New York, NY. 1995.

Rubin, Paul H.: The Theory of the Firm and the Structure of the
Franchise Contract. Journal of Law and Economics 21 (April 1978):
223–233.

Brickley, James A., Dark, Frederick H., and Weisbach, Michael S.:
The Agency Perspective on Franchising. Financial Management 20
(Spring 1991): 27–35.
Continental Franchise Review: Value is in the Eye of the Stockholder,
Special Report 26 (2) (1996): 1–6.
Continental Franchise Review: Getting a “Leg” Up on Competition Will
Add to Company’s Value 25 (24) (1995): 5–6.
Dant, Rajiv P., Paswan, Aduhesh K., and Kaufmann, Patrick J.: What
We Know About Ownership Redirection in Franchising: A MetaAnalysis. Journal of Retailing 72 (Fall 1996): 429–444.
Elton, Edwin J., and Gruber, Martin J.: Modern Portfolio Theory and
Investment Analysis, 5th ed., John Wiley & Sons, New York, NY
1995.
Fischer, Donald E., and Jordan, Ronald J.: Security Analysis & Portfolio
Management, 6th ed., Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. 1995.
Harrington, Diana R., Fabozzi, Frank J., and Folger, H. Russell: The
New Stock Market: A Complete Guide to the Latest Research, Analysis,
and Performance, Probus Publishing, Chicago, IL. 1990.
Jensen, Michael C.: Eclipse of the Public Corporation. Harvard Business Review 67 (5) (Sept./Oct. 1989): 61–74.
Kaufmann, Patrick J., and Dant, Rajiv P.: Multi-Unit Franchising:
Growth and Management Issues. Journal of Business Venturing 11
(5) (1996): 343–358.
Klott, Gary L.: The New York Times Complete Guide to Personal Investing, New York Times Books, New York, NY. 1987.
Koutsoyiannis, A.: Non-Price Decisions: The Firm in a Modern Context,
St. Martin’s Press, New York, NY. 1982.
Lafontaine, Francine: Contract Theory and Franchising: Some Empirical Results. Rand Journal of Economics 23(1992): 263–283.
Lafontaine, Francine, and Kaufmann, Patrick J.: The Evolution of
Ownership Patterns in Franchise Systems. Journal of Retailing 70
(2) (1994): 97–113.
Li, David D., and Li, Shan: A Theory of Corporate Scope and Financial
Structure. Journal of Finance 51 (2) (1996): 691–709.
March, James C.: The Business Firm as a Political Coalition. Journal
of Politics 24 (4) (1962): 662–678.
Murphy, Kevin J.: Corporate Performance and Managerial Remuneration. Journal of Politics 24 (4) (1962): 662–678.
Murphy, Kevin J.: Corporate Performance and Managerial Remuneration. Journal of Accounting and Economics 7(1–3) (1985): 11–42.
Myers, Randy: Metric Wars. CFO (Oct. 1996): 41–50.
Oxenfeldt, Alfred R., and Kelly, Anthony O.: Will Successful Franchise Systems Ultimately Become Wholly-Owned Chains? Journal
of Retailing 44 (4) (1968): 69–87.

224

J Busn Res
2000:50:217–224

P. J. Kaufmann et al.

Rudnitsky, Howard: Leaner Cuisine. Forbes (March 27, 1995): 43–44.
Shane, Scott: Hybrid Organizational Arrangements and Their Implications for Firm Growth and Survival: A Study of New Franchisors. Academy of Management Journal 39 (1) (1996): 216–234.

Stewart, G. Bennett III: The Quest for Value, Harper Business, New
York, NY. 1991.
Wallace, James S.: Adopting Residual Income-Based Compensation Plans,
University of California-Irvine Working Paper, 1996.

Sharp, Robert M.: Calculated Risk: A Master Plan for Common Stocks,
Dow Jones-Irwin, Homewood, IL. 1986.

Appendix A
The AV measure, NI is calculated in the model as follows:
NI 5 Rev 2 Exp
where Rev 5 RevFr 1 RevCo
RevFr 5 revenue from franchising 5 initial franchise fees (IFF) 1 periodic royalties (Roy)
RevCo 5 revenue from company units 5 gross sales at company units
and
Exp 5 ExpFr 1 ExpCo 1 Depreciation 1 Taxes
ExpFr 5 expenses of franchising 5 [exp of selling franchises (Sell) 1 exp of servicing [monitoring]
franchises (MonFr)]
ExpCo 5 expenses of company units 5 [operating exp of the units (OpExp) 1 exp of servicing
[monitoring] co units (MonCo)].
Re: Franchising:
IFF 5 $20,000 * number of new franchised units opened during period (NewFr)
Roy 5 0.06 * average gross sales of a franchised unit (AGrSalesFr) * average number of
franchised units open in period (A#UnitsFr)
A#UnitsFr 5 number of franchised units open at end of prior period 1 0.5 * NewFr
Sell 5 IFF
where Mon$Fr 5 $10,000
MonFr 5 Mon$Fr * A#UnitsFr,
Re: Company units:
OpExp 5 0.75 * RevCo
A#UnitsCo 5 number of company units open at end of prior period 1 0.5 * number of new
company units opened during period (NewCo )
MonCo 5 3 * Mon$Fr * A#UnitsCo
The EV measure, r, is calculated as follows:

r 5 NOPAT/Total Capital

where NOPAT 5 NI 1 Increase in Equity Equivalents in Period 1 Interest Expense after Tax
and

Total Capital 5 Total Debt (DbtTot) 1 Total Equity (EqTot) 1 Cumulative Total Equity Equivalents

Dokumen yang terkait

BAB II TINJAUAN PUSTAKA 2.1 Tinjauan Tentang Asam Jawa (Tamarindus indica) - EFEKTIVITAS EKSTRAK DAUN ASAM JAWA (Tamarindus indica L.) TERHADAP DAYA HAMBAT Staphylococcus epidermidis SEBAGAI SUMBER BELAJAR BIOLOGI - UMM Institutional Repository

0 0 19

BAB III METODOLOGI PENELITIAN 3.1 Jenis Penelitian - EFEKTIVITAS EKSTRAK DAUN ASAM JAWA (Tamarindus indica L.) TERHADAP DAYA HAMBAT Staphylococcus epidermidis SEBAGAI SUMBER BELAJAR BIOLOGI - UMM Institutional Repository

2 8 26

Resistensi Malathion dan Aktivitas Enzim Esterase Pada Populasi Nyamuk Aedes aegypti di Kabupaten Pekalongan Malathion Resistance And Esterase Enzyme Activity Of Aedes aegypti Population In Pekalongan Regency

0 0 10

ANGKA KEMATIAN DI BERBAGAIPROPINSI DI INDONESIA (DATA RISKESDAS 2007) Mortality Rate In Various Provinces Of Indonesia (Riskesdas Data 2007)

0 0 10

PENDIDIKAN DAN PEKERJAAN BERDASARKAN KUALITAS fflDUP PADA REMAJA (GAMBARAN DESKRIPTIF DATA RISKESDAS 2007) The Levels Of Education And Occupation Of Adolescence Based On Their Quality Of Life (Riskesdas 2007)

0 0 9

TREN PENYAKIT PENYEBAB KEMATIAN BAYI DAN ANAK BALITA DI INDONESIA DALAM PERIODE TAHUN 1992-2007 Trend Of Causes Of Death Of Infant And Children Under-Five Year Old In Indonesia In The Year Period 1992-2007

0 0 8

PAJANAN HG PADA PETAMBANG EMAS TRADISIONAL DI KABUPATEN GUNUNG MAS, KALIMANTAN TENGAH Mercury Exposure Of Traditional Miners In Gunung Mas District, Central Kalimantan Inswiasri, Haryoto Kusnoputranto

0 0 11

PERILAKU MASYARAKAT DALAM PENGELOLAAN SANITASI LINGKUNGAN PEMUKIMAN DI PERKEBUNAN KOPI KABUPATEN JEMBER (The Behaviour Of Society In The Management Of Environmental Sanitation At Coffee Plantation Residence In Jember Regency)

0 0 9

Political Economy Of Accounting (PEA)

0 2 32

A Conceptual Framework for Business Model Research

0 0 13