Antinomies of Christianity, Islam and the calculative sciences

Adelaide, Australia

Keywords Accounting, Christianity, Islam Abstract Capitalism, religion and science (including calculative sciences such as accounting) have

a long and turbulent relationship that, today, is manifest in the “War on Terror”. As social ideologies, religion and science have played a sometimes decisive influence in the history of capitalism. What can one learn from these past encounters to better understand their relationship today? This paper explores the historical origins of this relationship as a struggle over the ideals of the Enlightenment: – as decline of the modern and the rise of the postmodern. The paper begins by tracing the evolution of Christianities and their different potentials in both resisting and accommodating the extant social order. Islam, in contrast, has,until recently, enjoyed a relatively sheltered existence from capitalism, and today, some factions present a militant stance against the market and the liberal democratic state. Overall, the Enlightenment and modernist projects are judged to be jeopardy – a condition fostered by orthodox economics and accounting ideology, where it is now de rigueur to divide the secular from the non-secular, the normative from the positive, and the ethical from the pragmatic or realist. Finally, the mechanisms behind this Enlightenment regression are examined here using literary analysis, as a modest prelude to developing a new politics for a progressive accounting; one that seeks to restore the integrity and probity of the Enlightenment Ideal.

1. Introduction Christianity, Islam and accounting[1] each constitute a social ideology in the sense that they are systems of beliefs that inform conduct in everyday life (Althusser, 1969; Cleaver, 1979; Aronowitz, 1981; Eagleton, 1991)[2] This paper reviews their development since the Enlightenment, and their differential capacities to accommodate or subvert the Enlightenment project, and thus the extant social

The author would like to thank Mohammed Chabrak, Samira Ben Hammouda and Dr Nihel Chabrak (the latter at the Institute for National Telecommunications, France) for their extensive contributions to earlier drafts of this work. Special appreciation is also due to Ken McPhail and two anonymous reviewers, whose comments helped greatly in improving the understanding of

Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal

this material. The author is also indebted to Chris Carter and the Rev. Dr Julian Randel, both of

Vol. 17 No. 3, 2004

the University of St Andrews, and Hady Sy (Mullah and Dr of Islamic Theology in Senegal) and

pp. 442-475 q Emerald Group Publishing Limited

Peter Gillett (Rutgers University) for invaluable advice and guidance. Without any of these

0951-3574

contributions, this paper would not have been possible. Please do not quote from the text without

DOI 10.1108/09513570410545812

the permission of the author.

system (e.g., feudalism and capitalism). It is within this broader modernist struggle,

Enlightenment

that sections 2 through 7 undertake a historical reflection that paves the way for

and its

examining the integral relation between the “external” War on Terror, and “internal” domestic crises of racism, audit failures and corporate fraud.

discontents

The discussion begins by tracing the dynamic evolution of Christian ideologies (sections 2, 3 and 4). This includes their dialectical interpenetration of pre-Christian, mythological belief systems and the rise of science; including the

calculative/accounting sciences. The analysis in section 5 extends to “The insurgency of Islam”, that provides some vivid contrasts with particular Christian ideologies. “The Rise of calculative sciences” (section 6) takes accounting as its center piece. Accounting (calculus, and other computational sciences) are construed as different terrains over which the struggle for Enlightenment ideals are fought. This section traces accounting’s complex ideological lineage to philosophy, calculation, economics, and culture. This thematic focus – on the ideological milieu of accounting – continues in section 7 (“Obstacles to the development of a progressive politics”) and Section 8 (“Implications”).

2. Enlightenment Marx notes in the eighteenth century Brumaire that, “ . . . all facts and personages of great importance in world history occur, as it were, twice . . . the first time as tragedy, the second as farce”. (Marx, 1990, p. 15). As such, we might characterize the complex movements of the social history of the Enlightenment – as a dialectical transformation from tragedy (crisis) to farce (an unstable unity-of-opposites). The forlorn condition of the Enlightenment is postmodernity – the degraded state of modernist ideal, that today presents itself as a series of spurious dichotomies between the secular and the non-secular, between the normative and the positive, between the theoretical and the practical (or empirical), and between the ideal and the real (Tinker et al., 1982)[3]. But what were the Enlightenment’s antecedents? As a departure from (a largely Catholic) order, into an emergent form of capitalism, were they inevitably flawed from a bad seed?

Variously called “The Age of Reason”, or by some British historians, “The Illumination“, the Enlightenment is usually dated between 1650 and 1800 (Snyder, 1955, p. 7). Kant expressed its decisive historical character and mission in a famous passage in his “Response to the question: what is Enlightenment?” (1784):

Enlightenment is the liberation of man from his self-caused state of minority. Minority is the incapacity of using one’s understanding without the direction of another. This state of minority is self-caused when its source lies not in a lack of understanding but in a lack of determination and courage to use it without the assistance of another. Sapere aude! Dare to use your own understanding! is thus the motto of the Enlightenment.

In retrospect, such sentiments seem intellectually chauvinistic. The antecedents to Kant’s bravado were a complex of economic and political upheavals in the times in which he lived. They included improvements in agricultural productivity that led to surpluses, gluts, and price collapses in the rural economy. These and other stresses prefigured the eventual decline of the manorial system, a mass migration of dispossessed farm labor from country to town, the reconstitution and concentration of labor into town guilds, the rise of the burghers and the bourgeoisie class, etc (Dobb, 1973; Hunt, 1986). The growing consciousness that Kant embodied owes much to a

AAAJ

revolution in these prior materialistic conditions (Cornforth, 1973)[4]. Kant’s narrow

cultural and philosophical focus begs the question: “What were the different ideological forms that both confronted and galvanized the Enlightenment?”. Catholicism, or Church absolutism, was the first of a series of ideological opponents that resisted the incipient forces of capitalism, and thus much of the Enlightenment movement itself (Ravetz, 1973).

3. The Christian dialectic Catholic paternalism The ideology of medieval Catholic paternalism marshals the full symbolic authority of an earlier, Aristotelian view of society “ . . . the Christian corporate ethic, reflecting the fact that all of society was considered a single entity or corporation” (Hunt, 1986, p. 5):

This is a cosmic and a hierarchical understanding of society that runs from matter to the foot of God. At the center is the Earth, and centered upon Earth was man, and all the contents of the Universe are ordered around him and for him. In this fashion, all of the powerful ideological precepts from Aristotelian slave society were resurrected into the culture of early Christendom (Hunt, 1986, p. 5).

The early Catholic regimen of Christian paternalism stressed stability and order. Duties and responsibilities were clearly defined; with compliance required of all orders. Hence, “The Old Testament Jews quite literally regarded themselves as the children of one God” (Gray, 1963) and “The teachings of Christ in the New Testament carry on part of the Mosaic tradition . . . ” (Hunt, 1986, p. 5).

Hostility to wealth accumulation is frequently cited as a Catholic obstacle to the development of capitalism. This is clearly evidenced in the gospel according to Luke. Known as the “leveller among the apostles”, Hunt claims that Luke shows that Christ condemned the rich simply because they were rich and praised the poor simply because they were poor: “Woe unto you that are rich! . . . Woe unto you that are full! for ye shall hunger. Woe unto you that laugh now! for ye shall morn and weep”. (Hunt, 1986, p. 6).

Duty rather than wealth was the main concern in the medieval world. As Aquinas notes, “The rich man, if he does not give alms, is a thief” (Gray, 1963). Catholic paternalism could be, and was, used to “defend – as natural and just – the great inequalities and intense exploitation that flowed from the concentration of wealth and power in the hands of the Church and nobility” (Hunt, 1986, p. 9). Catholicism was founded on an economy that, in the Middle Ages, encompassed one third of the lands of Europe. Feudal ties, taxes and tribute formed an economic base for a superstructure of religious beliefs that, as Galileo among others discovered to their cost, posed a formidable adversary for Enlightenment thinkers (Tigar and Levy, 1977; Snyder, 1955, pp. 22-5).

Antinomies of Catholicism By the sixteenth century, Catholic paternalism was showing signs of strain from within and without. From within, the Church’s own economic hypocrisy was all too evident. It preached a personal gospel of severe proscriptions on money-lending and charging interest on loans, yet the economic excesses of the Vatican and many of the clergy belied this. The Church’s highly personalized system of economic ethics was increasingly out-of-sync with an emerging system of inter-regional and inter-national Antinomies of Catholicism By the sixteenth century, Catholic paternalism was showing signs of strain from within and without. From within, the Church’s own economic hypocrisy was all too evident. It preached a personal gospel of severe proscriptions on money-lending and charging interest on loans, yet the economic excesses of the Vatican and many of the clergy belied this. The Church’s highly personalized system of economic ethics was increasingly out-of-sync with an emerging system of inter-regional and inter-national

Enlightenment

the Black Plague which devastated one-quarter of its population.

and its

On top of its own internal failings, Catholicism was under increasing pressure from without. The secularization of Church functions under Henry VIII meant that the state,

discontents

in the form of God’s monarchy, assumed the role and functions of the old universal church. In the Glorious Revolution of 1688, the medieval worldview that underlay the Christian paternalist ethic was eclipsed. The disposal of monastic lands by the British

Crown in the wake of the Anglican revolt against Rome unleashed a wild spate of land speculation, spiralling rents and land prices. Although peasants heavily protested these developments until the seventeenth century, this victory of rural depopulation and the privatization of public lands signalled the institutionalization of the inalienable right to private property.

The English revolution in agricultural technology of the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries also precipitated the demise of Catholic morality. Generally, this foreshadowed a destruction of localized, self-sufficient communities, and a massive increase in physical and temporal interdependence, first through mercantilism, and then via capitalism (Smith, 1990). The explosion of export trade in wool from England and cost inflation at home led to the seizure of land for profitable redeployment to new forms of industry. Public fields and forests (commons) previously used for collective farming and fuel were fenced off and converted into pasture for sheep grazing. Landowners, themselves beset by financial pressures, reneged on ancient understandings, and drove peasants from their lands (only later to re-instate a few as renter-farmers, under the newly constituted “land-lords”).

As Tawney (1937) notes, these changes marked a turn in ideology, “away from that of the village based on a fellowship of mutual aid and a partnership of service and protection . . . to the pecuniary interests of a great proprietor” (Tawney, 1937; Smith, 1990). In this manner, a mechanistic law from without superseded the traditional balance of quasi-legal rights and obligations in communities. While focusing on individual rights, this law neglected the moral claims of the larger community to monitor and to exact common duties from individuals. A paramount shift is marked here in Western Society; from a society that is a synthesis of cooperative rights and obligations, authorized internally by common consent, to a society composed of a collection of individual interests, where rights and duties are warranted from without by a mechanistic law.

The Protestant synthesis The inner contradictions of the medieval order, including the incongruities of Catholic paternalism, culminated in the Reformation; a movement by religious people, who shared with Enlightenment thinkers, a dislike of the Church’s monopoly over the individual’s access and communion with God, and who could no longer tolerate Catholicism’s anachronistic hypocrisy.

The emergence of competing Protestant world views ended the monopoly of Catholicism’s unified spiritual vision of society. Protestantism, at the beginning of the Reformation, did not offer a new carte blanche attitude towards individual involvement in economic matters. On the contrary, the two great Reformation leaders, Luther (1483-1546) and Calvin (1509-1564), sought purer forms of the Christian cosmic order, which they felt, had been debased by the Roman Church. Luther and Calvin were

AAAJ

totally behind Paul’s affirmation in Romans that “sola fide” or faith alone could secure

salvation. Any intervention on the individual’s part could effect nothing to secure salvation. Calvin added to this a definite lurch towards predestination which would still be part of the Evangelical tradition (Apocalypse is used to support this contention).

A Catholic version of this “heresy” can be found in Jansenism which dates from the eighteenth century French theologian, Jansenius[5].

Luther’s vision sought a return to a divine past that pre-existed those institutions of Roman Catholicism that had usurped the individual’s opportunity to find a divine union with God[6]. This return to a simpler agrarian order, was based on individual asceticism and commitment to God, and necessitated the abolition of all barriers between the ordained and the laity. The Bible and one’s conscience were all that was needed[7].

Calvin, like Luther, envisaged a purer, unified social order, in which all human activity came under the guidance of Divine Law. Unlike Luther, and the Roman Church, Calvinism came to terms with extant social realities and the emergent social order. It accepted the new role of business as a legitimate aspect of human endeavor. As Tawney (1937) notes, “Its enemy was not the accumulation of riches, but their misuse for the purposes of self-indulgence or ostentation” (Tawney, 1937). In this way, Calvinism sought to reintegrate the increasingly alienated spheres of economy and religion. It gave moral sanction to the freer movement of the market principle, yet still attempted to keep the market’s most destructive tendencies under tight control. The new businessman’s activities were never “for himself”, but were always sublimated to

a religious zeal that his work was to manifest devotion to God through selfless diligence. This original vision spoke more of a collective identity of followers under a communal order – with rights and responsibilities – than free-market individualism often attributed to late Calvinism. In this sense, Calvin’s theology, like Luther’s, probably inadvertently, helped secure the hegemony of modern capitalism.

Puritanism constituted an even deeper fusion of the Christian and an economic spirit. At its root, it rejected the theses of Luther and Calvin that good works could gain God’s grace. Emerging from Calvin’s interpretation of the Protestant idea of pre-destination, Puritanism held that one’s ultimate salvation is already predestined at birth. With such a contingency, life then becomes a trial of faith in discovering and manifesting one’s destiny – as one of the chosen, or as one of the damned. That aim is not personal salvation, but the glorification of God – sought, not by prayer alone, but by action; the sanctification of the world by strife and labor.

Such a world view fermented a group of followers described as “an earnest, zealous, godly generation, scorning delights, punctual in labor, constant in prayer, thrifty and thriving” and believing “that labor and industry is their duty towards God” (Jennings and Doddridge, 1810). Further, they were economically independent, educated and having “a certain decent pride in their status, revealed at once in their determination to live their own lives, . . . and in a somewhat arrogant contempt for those who, either through weakness of character, or through economic helplessness, were less resolute, less vigorous and masterful, than themselves” (Jennings and Doddridge, 1810).

The Puritan vision was well suited to the new individualistic economic order emerging in the seventeenth century. As part of the initial Protestant urge, Puritanism sought to terminate any external mediation between a person and God. Additionally, “the moral self-sufficiency of the Puritan nerved his will, but it corroded his sense of social solidarity” (Jennings and Doddridge, 1810). The Puritan as an individual and as The Puritan vision was well suited to the new individualistic economic order emerging in the seventeenth century. As part of the initial Protestant urge, Puritanism sought to terminate any external mediation between a person and God. Additionally, “the moral self-sufficiency of the Puritan nerved his will, but it corroded his sense of social solidarity” (Jennings and Doddridge, 1810). The Puritan as an individual and as

Enlightenment

vision. Further, their enduring quest to prove an already pre- determined salvation led

and its

Puritans to view failure and poverty as manifestations of damnation. This not only promoted a competitive instinct through fear of failure, but also an inclination to be,

discontents

“moved less by compassion for his erring brethren than by impatient indignation at the blindness of others” (Jennings and Doddridge, 1810). In the final analysis, Puritanism is Christendom’s “coming home” for capitalism: it supplies a deep union of the Christian

vision with market principles of competition, self-interest and financial success.

4. Catholic mythology in capitalism The historical travails of Christian institutions betray a complex of dialectical progressions. This is not a narrative of “progress” of equilibrium-prone movement, but an unstable trajectory of disequilibriums, best portrayed in dialectical terms. This formulation construes the socio-history of capitalism and christianities as a evolving identity, composed of contradictory elements from the past and present. At each point in time, this precarious synthesis is an unsteady “interpenetration of opposites” or “unity of difference” (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979). A dramatic illustration of these dialectical shifts may be found in the mythological legacy that Roman Catholicism has bestowed on the everyday life of modern capitalism.

Catholicism itself never escaped from its mythological ancestry. Indeed, even today, it continues to deploy pre-Christian mythological symbolism to great effect. In anthropological terms, Catholic dogma regarding papal infallability retains elements of God-King religions, such as that practiced by some Egyptian pharaohs[8]. Authority under such belief systems is embodied in the Almighty here on Earth; a supernatural being that supplies a terrible and divine presence[9]. Protestantism dethroned Catholicism’s infallible Shepherd of the Lord, and (modestly) crowns man [sic] as maker of his own destiny. The mythological crowning of man is the final chapter where he becomes the master of his own destiny (Tawney, 1937)[10]. This metamorphosis of Christianity into Protestantism is the quintessence of Kant’s dictum: “Dare to use your understanding”.

Center-stage in this anthropology is the evolution of human control over the conditions of existence; beginning with control over Nature, but then broadening to include control over the populace (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979, p. xviii, pp. 3-42). Instruments of social control include mythology, religions, languages, cultures, histories, and institutions. The Judeo-Catholic allegory of The Fall, and man’s expulsion from the Garden of Eden, is the mythological explanation of the estrangement of man from God; the first step on Kant’s path, away from a “state of minority” and blind-faith in a Benevolent Almighty. Adam and Eve disobeyed God, and – in following the serpent – relinquished God’s paradise in favor of the tree of knowledge; a path of growing independence that culminates in modern science and technology.

Certain patterns of control repeat themselves across time and civilizations. These patterns cluster into two primary forms: reciprocity and mimesis (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979)[11]. The prayer-penance levied at the Confession is, for instance, part of a reciprocal relation: the sacrifice (prayer) is given to obtain a reciprocal absolution and forgiveness of sins[12]. In Christian ideology, God-the-Father sacrificed his Only Son (symbolized in Catholic phraseology as, “The Lamb of God”) because the

AAAJ

death of God is sufficient reciprocally equivalent-in-exchange to expunge the stain of

Adam and Eve’s Original Sin[13]. In his own sacrificial crucifixion, the Redeemer restored to humankind the possibility of salvation. In the modern Catholic mass, this sacrifice is re-enacted in the sacrament (and miracle) of The Eucharist. On each occasion of this “Offering”, the priest tenders “Christ’s body and blood” in exchange for humankind’s absolution. In Catholic ideology, the transformation of the bread and

wine into Christ’s body and blood is a miracle repeated at every mass. The mass-sacrifice, as a form of reciprocity, seeks forgiveness and absolution. It assumes that, “ . . . everything that happens must atone for having happened” (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979, p. 12).

Religions in antiquity contained a special notion of control that only partly presaged that found in science today. Reciprocity, absolution, atonement, and retribution are rituals that aspire to control-the-uncontrollable; they are pervasive across time and different communities. The deities that inhabited the forces-of-nature were not subdued by man with a Kantian audacity, but were invariably feared, treated guardedly, known to be fickle, unpredictable, mischievous, and even malevolent (Levi-Strauss, 1963; Fitzpatrick, 1992). Spirits weren’t conquered, but quieted by duplicity, compromise, humor, and placation. Mimical practices controlled by assuming the semblance of a threatening part of Nature (the spirits of sickness, the weather, pestilence, death, etc). Sacrifice, repeated identification, incantation, prayer, and recurring pictorial and hieroglyphic patterns, are all persistent mimical motifs that aim to control the uncontrollable by appeasement. Thus, the magician “ . . . imitates demons; in order to frighten them or appease them, he behaves frighteningly or makes gestures of appeasement . . . his task is impersonation” (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979, p. 9).

The Enlightenment and Catholic campaign against myth sought to abolish superstition, exorcise the gods, and erase magic. Yet both Catholicism and science proceeded by taking-on the methods of myth (and in doing so, they eventually revert to myth). The continuity between myth and science is reflected in their common pursuit of control, and the means for accomplishing control. Science inherits from myth its reliance on repetition, shown today in techniques of correlation analysis, pattern recognition, regression analysis, analysis of variance, etc. The search for repetitive patterns, regularities or order, epitomizes the scientific method, and were central to Bacon’s characterization of his experimental method (the precursor to modern Empiricism):

Man, who is the servant and the interpreter of nature, can act and understand no further than he has observed, either in operation, or in contemplation, or the method and order or nature (Snyder, 1955, p. 26).

Bacon, who Voltaire described as, “the father of the experimental philosophy”, expressed a clear vision of the potential of this new knowledge:

Knowledge and human power are synonymous, since the ignorance of the cause frustrates the effect; for nature is only subdued by submission, and that which in contemplative philosophy corresponds with the cause in practical science becomes the rule (Snyder, 1955, p. 96).

Science and its early discontents Even the early luminaries dimly understood the darker side of subjugating Nature to human ends. Their reservations reflect a mixture of nostalgia and prescience. Bacon and Descartes, although disbelieving in magical powers, retained a moral sense. In his

Utopian “New Atlantis”, Bacon had the sages of Solomon’s House decide which secrets

Enlightenment

they would reveal to the State, and which they would not. With some foresight of

and its

problems to come, Descartes offered science a “scientist’s oath” of classic simplicity: that, “I would not engage on projects which can be useful to some only by being

discontents

harmful to others” (Ravetz, 1973, p. 63)[14]. It was Francis Bacon, remembered in rather vulgar terms for his equation of power and knowledge, who offered a most sober warning:

Lastly, I would address one general admonition to all; that they consider what are the true ends of knowledge, and that they seek it not either for pleasure of mind, or for contention, or for superiority to others, or for profit, or fame, or power, or any of these inferior things; but for the benefit and use of life; and that they perfect and govern it in charity. For it was from lust of power that the angels fell, from lust of knowledge that men fell; but of charity there can be no excess, neither did angel or man ever come in danger by it (Bacon, 1825).

Other critics shared these concerns. Edmund Burke voiced his doubts and disgust at the excesses of the French Revolution. Malthus, in countering Condorcet’s optimism, argued the impossibility of escaping the limits of natural scarcity and wants (Harvey, 1989, p. 15). Weber has argued that:

. . . the hope and expectation of the Enlightenment thinkers was a bitter and ironic illusion. They maintained a strong link between the growth of science, rationality, and universal

human freedom. But when unmasked and understood, the legacy of the Enlightenment was the triumph of... purposive -instrumental rationality . . . [that] . . . infects the entire range of social and cultural life, encompassing economic structures, law, bureaucratic administration, and even the arts . . . [leading to] . . . an “iron cage” of bureaucratic rationality from which there is no escape (Bernstein, 1985, p. 5).

Why did the best laid plans of Bacon and Descartes, architects of the Enlightenment, regress into new forms of barbarity? For Adorno and Horkheimer, “ . . . the sanction of fate is that, in retribution, it relentlessly remakes what has already been” (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979, p. 12). Why did the quest for freedom from want revert to a subordination of nature; including human nature? The answer lies, in part, in the partial manner in which modernism itself has appropriated myth.

Science’s regressions to myth Labor process theorists hold that the first step in the division of labor is that between thought and action, head and hand, or planning and execution (Pollard, 1965; Braverman, 1998). Yet, this division is predated by a more fundamental schism in

mythology: between logos and reality, subject and object, (the latter being the target of the subject’s attention) that has had an even more deleterious impact on post-Enlightenment, post-modern science (Tinker et al., 1982):

The separation of the animate and the inanimate, the occupation of certain places by demons and deities, first arises from [this] pre-animism, which contains the first lines of the separation of subject and object. When the tree is no longer approached merely as tree, but as evidence for an Other, as the location of mana, language expresses the contradiction that something is itself, and one and the same time something other than itself, identical and not identical (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979, p. 15).

Cartesian classification, and the search for relations across categories, represents an important departure from these prior forms of knowledge (Tinker et al., 1982; Tinker

AAAJ

and Yuthas, 1995). Items that are assigned to classes obtain a universal

interchangeability with other members of the class. “ . . 17,3 . nature becomes the chaotic

matter of mere classification” (Tinker and Yuthas, 1995, p. 10). Atoms, entrepreneurs, voters, trees, patients and dogs lose there uniqueness; they become, by definition, fungible within their groupings[15]. This obliteration of “differance” – otherness – is what Derrida noted (much later) to be the tyranny of logos – the sovereignty of ideas

(Derrida, 1978; Ryan, 1982): Laboratory research instances Derrida’s “tyranny of the logos”. It offers an illusory

controllability by positing a clear separation between the observed and the observer. In reality, there is no separation between subject and object because the existence of object includes how we see it and how we construct our consciousness from our experiences. Research therefore requires a cognizance of this understanding, and the understanding of others of different objects. There is no opposition between object and subject – one is embedded in the other (the subject is in the object). There is no “control” of objects in a conventional sense; but only a mutual transformation of self-and-other (Chabrak, 2002).

The distancing of subject and object in science is a bifurcation that is ultimately self-defeating. Normal science rarely heeds this epistemic caution. Cartesian dualisms (either/or classification) typically ignore internal or implicit relations, and hence interdependences that, in reality, may eventually erupt into second-order effects and unintended consequences (Ollman, 1976)., In contrast, dialectical analysis and magical practices take these cautions very seriously: While magic and science aspire to forms of control, “[M]agic pursues aims . . . by mimesis – not by progressively distancing itself from the object.” (Adorno and Horkheimer, 1979, p. 11). In dialectics, Hegel dramatized the importance of integral (dialectical) relations in discussing the master-slave relation, showing the integral dependence of the master on the slave just as much as the reverse (Hegel, 1977, pp. 104-38). The repression of the slave – beyond the limits and entitlements of a slave – eventually leads to the master’s own self-repression.

The Cartesian fallacy of universal commensurability, and its struggle to abolish difference, underlies the Enlightenment’s reversion to myth. This Cartesian estrangement between Self-and-Other in the philosophical realm, has blood brothers at the materialistic level; in the social system of capitalism. Specifically, there is a direct correspondence between the levelling of difference by Cartesian thought, and levelling in the economy, first in the condensation of value into the money-form, and second, in the reduction of labor to labor power in the capitalist labor process (Braverman, 1998; Fromm, 1973; Marcuse, 1964).

Traditionally, value was not seen in merely quantified terms; as the exchange rates between objects transferred at market. It also contained a qualitative worth of a person’s skills and abilities. Value always had a wide variety of subjective meanings, from the pretty (precious stone) to the useful (a carpenter’s skill). When one traded and bartered, a qualitative as well as quantitative exchange occurred. Beginning in the sixteenth century, price marking systems transformed both products and factors of production into commodities, or objects of value quantifiable by money. As labor and capital markets evolved, money served as a homogenizing force for transforming all value into an objective quantification. Hence, the precious stone becomes commensurate with three weeks of the carpenter’s skilled work; all other qualities – the variegations in class, religion and ethnicity, slip from view. Money assumes a Traditionally, value was not seen in merely quantified terms; as the exchange rates between objects transferred at market. It also contained a qualitative worth of a person’s skills and abilities. Value always had a wide variety of subjective meanings, from the pretty (precious stone) to the useful (a carpenter’s skill). When one traded and bartered, a qualitative as well as quantitative exchange occurred. Beginning in the sixteenth century, price marking systems transformed both products and factors of production into commodities, or objects of value quantifiable by money. As labor and capital markets evolved, money served as a homogenizing force for transforming all value into an objective quantification. Hence, the precious stone becomes commensurate with three weeks of the carpenter’s skilled work; all other qualities – the variegations in class, religion and ethnicity, slip from view. Money assumes a

Enlightenment

that may be essential to a fully-lived experience.

and its

Nowhere is this regression more dramatically evident than in regard to work and the labor process. “Labor” embodies the full rich complexity of humanity.

discontents

“Labor-power”, in contrast, is that shard of humanity that is “productive” in a surplus value generating sense. Under capitalism, accumulation through competitive market processes elevates labor power (abstract labor) to overshadow labor (Elson,

1979). As such, it defaces, mutilates, and erases all other human qualities and potentialities that compose a full person.

Accounting is Descartes’ comprador in the growing sphere of capitalist commodity production. The privileging of profit (the phenomenal form of surplus value) in financial statements is the practical means by which capital accumulation subordinates labor. Hence, that slice of human activity that is most “efficient” and “productive” (labor power) belittles all other human qualities and potentials (labor). Accounting is the instrument of Cartesian selection and exclusion at its most potent. As Enlightement’s ambassador in modern capitalism, accounting is the market executioner of systemic repression. In the tradition of the Enlightenment reversion into self-repression, labor power – aided and abetted by accounting – cannibalizes its own foundations in labor, and thus maims human growth and potential (Braverman, 1998, ch.1; Tinker, 2002).

This treachery of labor power manifests itself through the spectrum of crises that typify capitalism. In the workplace, the alienation of labor power from labor manifests itself in the subordination of labor to efficiency and productivity (for producing surplus value in its phenomenal form of profit) (Allen, 1975; Braverman, 1998; Cleaver, 1979). Beyond the workplace, the imbalance engendered by the pursuit of efficiency results in

a consumption crisis, expressed in periodic gluts of overproduction, and intense pressure to dispose of surpluses with Veblen’s publicity engineers; a ”culture industry, and a ubiquitous cult of consumerism” (Illich, 1971; Scitovsky; 1975). “Efficiency” underpins the environmental crisis, induced by an imprudent and ruthless exploitation of natural resources – a domination of “The Other” – where Nature’s revenge looks increasingly imminent (Tinker and Gray, 2002). There is no better demonstration of the self-destructive propensities of Cartesian analysis than in the rapacious treatment of Nature[16]. Such conduct is only possible when Nature is treated as “The Other” and thus free for humans to exploit with impunity.

Finally, the appetite for surplus expropriation by capital has made possible (and necessary) a massive expansion in, what Mandel (1975) terms, “the fourth department”:

a military industrial complex in Europe and the USA, that completely fulfills Eisenhower’s cautionary words some 40 years ago (Eisenhower, 1961)[17]. This coercive apparatus (understood in its widest sense) has become vital for regulating dissent at home and abroad (Kidron, 1974; Chwastiak, 1996, 1998).

Christianity has long-been in the forefront of religious engagement in the formation of capitalism. Recently, Islam has enjoined the struggle against capitalism in a visible and sometimes dramatic manner. Unlike Christianity, Islam is not so directly concerned directly implicated in defending the ideal of the Enlightenment (the latter being commonly understood as European in time and space, notwithstanding the non-European antecedents). Nevertheless, I will argue that there is some commonality between Christians and Muslims in resisting Capitalism’s assault on the Enlightenment project.

AAAJ

5. The insurgency of Islam

Like Christianity, Islam is not monolithic: they each exhibit a diversity of postures towards capitalism, ranging from militancy to acquiescence[18]. Islam’s historical and dialectical development follows a quite different path from that of Christianity and Catholicism. Capitalism has quelled the Protestant rebellion, and has sought to marginalize the Catholic orthodoxy and absorbed its mysticism into its scientific

practices. This “interpenetration-of-opposites” reflects the partiality of the “resolution” on all counts. Catholicism, for instance, has seen the rise of liberation theology from within its own ranks. Islam, has, until recently, managed to stand apart from capitalism, and has thus preserved some independence and identity[19]. This capacity to resist assimilation poses a special threat to capitalism, and thus its demonization is predictable. So too is the upsurge in racism and discrimination directed at Arabs and Muslims.

While hostility to Islam and Muslims often operates at a visceral and intuitive level, there are also objective reasons for capitalism to treat Islam as an insurgency. Ironically, many of Islam’s traditional values are the same ideals as those cherished in the original Enlightenment. Capitalism is therefore returning to an old battleground; one on which it sought to overthrow[20] the early Enlightenment. We find these “early” Enlightenment values nurtured in mainstream Islam (that is, an Islam that relies only on a direct reading of the Koran, of the kind offered here). First, Islam is a religion that privileges “the innate” moderate and positive qualities of Man, and the importance of knowledge in their development. Material and spiritual life are not bifurcated; they form part of an essential unity. Knowledge is privileged because it fosters human integrity. This knowledge is neither cerebral nor practical, but composed of a holistic relation between belief and behavior, that gives pride of place to a civilized development of humanity. Such notions contrast with priorities of capitalism (to accumulate capital) and Judeo-Christianity (to serve a reified deity).

Islam is “Enlightenment”, and for capitalism – revolutionary – in that it rejects the division of the secular and the non-secular, and more generally, the separation between church and state. Indeed, Islam is not merely a “personal” religion; but, as the Koran shows in great detail, is also an organization for society, its institutions, as well as a guide for conduct of individuals within that institutional and social context. Consequently, the Koran itself is the authority for resisting the kind of ceasefire-agreement with the state that Christianities in the West have acceded to, where the secular has surrendered to the non-secular the realms of politics, education, the workplace, and economic relations.

In the realm of science, Islam remains holistic or dialectical, where, for instance, the health of the spirit and body and mind are treated as a unity[21]. It thereby stands against many of the Cartesian dualisms that typify the Enlightenment’s regression under capitalism – with the attendant subordination of man. We consider each of these areas in greater detail below.

The importance of knowledge in Islam Islam’s divergence from capitalism and Catholicism is evident from the very outset in their differing accounts of “The Fall”. The view of man in the Qur-an, man is that of someone tainted by an Original Sin that requires repentence and atonement; but a person made in God’s likeness. These are sentiments shared by Islam and the humanistic impulse of the early Enlightenment (Novack, 1966). Knowledge is the keystone to forming beliefs and establishing reflectively mediated behavior.

The Islamic positivity towards knowledge also exists in progressive strands of

Enlightenment

Catholicism, however the institutionalized variant confronting the early Enlightenment

and its

tended to view knowledge is either a poisoned fruit or having a cautiously contingent status. As Landes (1998), notes, the reactionary response of the Church in Spain to the

discontents

challenges of Protestantism led to slower economic growth than in Northern Europe. The Church not only denounced Luther, it prohibited reading and publishing heretical texts, and introduced the death penalty for reading foreign texts. After 400 years, Rome

has still to rehabilitate Galileo [22]. In Islam, knowledge – especially self-knowledge – has first priority. A Jihad has been scandalized by some Muslims and Christians as a “Holy War”, however for many moderates, and in the Koran itself, pre-eminence is given to knowledge and the integrity of conscience. The “Big” Jihad is the struggle against oneself and one’s passions. It is an effort to foster a conscience to control against corruption. The “small” jihad (Aljihad alsghar) consists of repairing an injustice (at the limit, war), but even here, there is a religious prohibition against aggression because life is sacred (Surat Al-r’ad, 11, Surat al-maida, 32). According to these respected, authoritative, and thus widely accepted readings of the Koran, the representation of the Jihad – as a war to convert people to islam – is completely false.

The Western reconstruction of the idea of Islam bares little resemblance to Islam as practiced by millions of Muslims. It is instructive to recount the West’s ideological reconstruction of Islam through the anticipations of George Orwell’s book, 1984. In an Orwellian world, Islam has become a nightmarish composite of Oceana’s mortal enemies: Eurasia and Eastasia. In modern America’s “Ministry of Fiction” (the spin-doctored media) Bin Laden stars as Orwell’s “enemy of the people”: Emmanuel Goldstein: Like Emmanuel Goldstein, Bin Laden’s actual existence has become quite irrelevant to his symbolic appropriation:

He was the primal traitor, the earliest defiler of . . . purity. All subsequent crimes . . . all treacheries, acts of sabotage, heresies, deviations, sprang directly out of his teachings. Somewhere or other he was still alive and hatching his conspiracies; perhaps somewhere beyond the sea, under the protection of his foreign paymasters; perhaps even . . . so it was occasionally rumored . . . in some hiding place in Oceania itself (Orwell, 1950, p. 14).

Paradoxically, the Islamic Jihad protects religious, constitutional, and legal rights and those freedoms that today have little more than rhetorical status in Western capitalism. Freedom under capitalism, was always ambiguous. It began with making “free-men” (free from the feudal ties and serfdom) who then became “unfree” wage labor in that they were now deprived (freed) of all their feudal entitlements (and thus were free to “starve under the bridges of Paris”). In contrast, in Islam, it is freedom and justice for the development of innate capacities that is sought, not freedom to be bought as wage labor by capital. Again, these subversive possibilities of Islam – shared with some Judeo-Christian religions – are evident in the importance it attaches to the moral, conscious, and practical ennoblement of individuals and the community. This is the early Enlightenment project that, in postmodernism, is in peril.

Islam as a social constitution Islam is simultaneously a religion, and a social constitution, because instructs Muslims in both how to worship and how they should conduct themselves with others (individuals, group, family, nation). The West has borrowed these precepts liberally

AAAJ

(but usually unacknowledged) from the centuries old traditions of Islam: the principles

established by the League of Nations in regulating relationships between nation states, and the ideals of the French Revolution (freedom, equality and fraternity) derive from experience from previously functioning Islamic societies. Many institutions established in Europe under Napoleon I was similarly inspired after his Egyptian campaign. There is no explicit prohibition against private property or capitalism in an

Islamic social order, although many of its excesses would be deemed unacceptable[23]. Holistic analysis

Bifurcations inspired by Cartesian analysis have aided in compromising the Enlightenment project. The scientific process of classifying, equalizing, levelling, and then privileging certain qualities, while silencing others, is the poison chalice of the Cartesian legacy (Ryan, 1982). Labor power evacuates labor, the economic represses the social, logos ejects language, money replaces values, normality humiliates the deviant, efficiency extinguishes beauty, “skill” drives out craftsmanship, cost precedes quality, and instrumentalism eclipses affection. In each case, Cartesian exclusion and privileging forms an unholy alliance with repressive social interests (Ryan, 1982). Islam, in its blissful innocence from negligible exposure to capitalism, retains an affinity with religions of antiquity and their practices of specific representation, which preserve the specificity of the individual. Islamic law is a process of resolving disputes by preserving uniqueness of each case. The process is “casuistic” in that it privileges individuality (Chabrak, 2002).

A commonplace lament in modern science is with the dysfunctional schism between “fact and value”, a distinction that, in recent months, accountants, with their own nomenclature of normative and positive, are coming to regret (Gouldner, 1975). This schism reaches to the highest level. The division of labor of conventional philosophy, into language, mind, ethics (axiology) and practice (pragmatism) ensures that none are adequate to Aristotle’s invocation to, “live an ethical life” (Pirsig,1974; Caws, 1965). However, this dualism pales by comparison with the grander version that has played on the stage of capitalism: the triumphant de-secularization of the state, ushered-in by Henry VIII, and its successful enshrinement in the American constitution. Islam, in contrast, has so far, largely escaped such history; the Koran elevates both the unity of the spiritual and material character of people. It is “moderate” in its recognition that does not ordain either a purely ascetic, or an essentially materialist life. It seeks a virtuous conduct that, on one hand, must be principled, and on the other, must be practical. These qualities are disengaged in market capitalism: principles are for the home, and practicalities are for work.

Finally, the civilizations incorporated under the Islamic empire celebrated unity in diversity by drawing from all sources for their development. This tolerance of difference stands in contrast with the totalizing mission of Western capitalism (although not all forms of Christianity) where colonized identities are viewed as “primitive” and in need of “civilizing” (as under such ideologies of “Manifest Destiny”, and the “White man’s Burden”). In contrast, in Islamic architecture, mosques are constructed in a style that honors local traditions (Indonesian, Tunisian, Egyptian, etc). Similarly, knowledge vital to the development of science in the Islamic empire harnessed the efforts of scholars from all religions – Christians, Jews, Indians and Muslims – who were all supported for their contributions to the human advancement.

It would be naı¨ve to assume that such benign tolerance was total; just as it is also

Enlightenment

important to remember that Muslim’s didn’t instigated the crusades.

and its

For reasons of history, Islam – as a system of beliefs and an everyday practice – has avoided being engulfed by capitalism. Yet already the Muslim and Arab world is

discontents

now under siege and seriously divided. Pressures from within and outside Turkey and Iran instance this. The intervention in local politics to change juridical systems, the de-secularization (or Christianization) of education, attempts to supplant Arabic (the