Model II Model III

154 Friend and Lang 1988 use a dummy variable to represent the existence of external block shareholders with a holding of 10 or more of a firm‘s outstanding stock. This study extends Friend and Lang 1988 by using the proportion of outstanding shares owned by external block holders. The two variables used to control for risk are: SIZE = natural log total assets . Many studies suggest that firm size is one important factor, which affects a firm‘s debt policy and therefore risk Scott and Martin 1975, Ferri and Jones 1979, Agrawal and Nagarajan 1990. IND = zero-one dummy variable for industry classification, where IND = 1 if industrial company and IND = 0 if natural resources company . A more detailed industrial classification is not used because the increase in the number of dummy variables imposes too severe restriction on the degrees of freedom in the regression. It is argued that industry class is a potential determinant of capital structure because firms, in the same industry, face similar demand and supply conditions, and thus have similar risk characteristics Scott and Martin 1975, Ferri and Jones 1979. The three variables used to control for agency costs are: GROWTH = the annual percentage change in total assets . Titman and Wessels 1988 suggest that a firm‘s growth opportunities are a good proxy for the agency costs of debt. They suggest that the tendency to invest sub-optimally to expropriate wealth from a firm‘s debt holders is likely to be higher for firms in growing industries. On the other hand, growth may also be an indicator of profitability and success of the firm. If this is the case, GROWTH will be a proxy for available internal funds. FCF is a direct measure of Jensen’s 1986 free cash flow hypothesis . The free cash flow hypothesis states that managers endowed with excessive free cash flows will invest sub- optimally rather than paying the free cash flow out to shareholders. Jensen 1986 predicts that firms with excessive free cash flow are likely to have higher leverage. FCF is defined in a similar manner to Lehn and Poulsen 1989. PROF = operating income before interest and taxes scaled by total assets . Indicators of a firm‘s profitability include ratios of operating income over sales and operating income over total assets Titman and Wessels 1988 and ratios of average earnings before interest and taxes over total assets Wald 1995. The variable used to control for asset specificity is: INTA = Total Intangibles ÷ Total Assets . Balakrishnan and Fox 1993 argue that asset specificity creates problems for debt financing due to the non-redeploy ability characteristics of specific assets. More specifically, asset specificity adversely affects a firm‘s ability to borrow. Balakrishnan and Fox 1993 suggest that examples of firm-specific assets are intangible assets such as brand names, research and development expenditure and other reputational investments. The last explanatory variable is used to control for the effect of taxes: NDTS = Annual Depreciation Expense ÷ Total Assets . NDTS variable is used to capture the non-debt tax shields argument put forward by DeAngelo and Masulis 1980. They argue that the greater the level of non-debt tax shields, the lower is the benefit of additional debt. Thus, all else equal, firms with higher non-debt tax shields are expected to receive lower tax benefits from issuing debt and therefore will utilize less debt.

2. Model II

To test for the hypothesized curvilinear relationship between managerial share ownership and capital structure as proposed by Brailsford et al. 2002, the managerial share ownership variable and the square of managerial share ownership variable is augmented to the regression model: Ln DE it = α +  MSO it +  1 MSO 2 it +  2 SIZE it +  3 IND it +  4 GROWTH it +  5 PROF it +  6 FCF it +  7 INTA +  8 NDTS + e it 2 155 where: MSO = = percentage of ordinary shares owned by all executive and non-executive directors. Share ownership of corporate directors are used by Morck et a. 1988 and Keasey et a. 1994, amongst others to proxy for managerial share ownership. Other variables are as previously described in Model I.

3. Model III

Finally, a joint test is used to investigate the third and fourth hypotheses, which explore the relationship between external block ownership and leverage at different levels of managerial share ownership. Specifically, the third hypothesis predicts that external block ownership and debt are positively related when the level of managerial share ownership is low. The fourth hypothesis predicts that at high levels of managerial share ownership, the association between external block ownership and the firm‘s debt ratio is less significant than at low levels of managerial share ownership, since the positive monitoring effect of external block ownership is offset by the negative entrenchment effect associated with managerial share ownership. To test these two hypotheses, a dummy variable D, denoting different levels of managerial share ownership is employed. D takes the value of 0 if the level of managerial share ownership is less than 20. When managerial share ownership is 20 or more D takes the value of 1. While there is generally little theoretical justification for the particular cut-off, the 20 level has been used in several previous studies Brailsford et al., 2002. For example, Hermalin and Weisbach 1991 find that the entrenchment effect of managerial share ownership sets in after 20 of managerial share ownership. The natural log of DE is then regressed against MSO, MSO 2 , EBO, DEBO and the control variables: Ln DE it = α +  MSO it +  1 MSO 2 it +  2 EBO it +  3 DEBO it +  4 SIZE it +  5 IND it +  6 GROWTH it +  7 PROF it +  8 FCF it +  9 INTA +  10 NDTS + e it 3 The coefficient on the EBO variable reflects the relation between external block ownership and the debt level when the level of managerial share ownership is low. The coefficient on the DEBO it variable then reflects the difference in the external block ownership and leverage relationship between high and low levels of managerial share ownership. In order to infer the relationship between external block ownership and leverage at high levels of managerial share ownership, the coefficient β 3 is added to the coefficient β 2 . In other words, the sum of β 2 and β 3 gives the slope for the relationship between external block ownership and leverage when the level of managerial share ownership is high. RESULT AND ANALYSIS 1. The effect of external block ownership on capital structure In general, all control variables, except External Block Ownership EBO, Size, and Industry, are positively skewed. Correlation analysis Table 5 shows that some explanatory variables are significantly correlated. First, there is significant negative correlation between the SIZE and FCF variables -0.195, even though the correlation is quite small. This may be quite surprising since larger firms normally are expected to have higher free cash flow. Free cash flows have been identified in the literature as being in evidence in large, diversified firms Berger and Ofek 1995, Smith and Kim 1994. However, by considering the effect of financial crisis on East Asia firms‘ asset and the ability to generate free cash flow, this phenomena at least can explain this effect. 156 Table 5 : Coefficient Correlation Independent Variable MSO MSO2 EBO DEBO SIZE Industry Growth PROF FCF INTA NDTS MSO 1.000 .920 -.479 .846 -.158 .037 .045 .042 .045 -.082 .001 MSO2 .920 1.000 -.371 .755 -.101 .016 .023 .041 .035 -.055 .028 EBO -.479 -.371 1.000 -.355 .055 -.053 -.161 -.112 .017 .065 -.026 DEBO .846 .755 -.355 1.000 -.157 .001 -.012 -.015 .032 -.077 .000 SIZE -.158 -.101 .055 -.157 1.000 -.045 -.047 -.006 -.195 .033 .005 Industry .037 .016 -.053 .001 -.045 1.000 .065 -.071 .028 .066 -.141 Growth .045 .023 -.161 -.012 -.047 .065 1.000 .089 -.037 .014 -.030 PROF .042 .041 -.112 -.015 -.006 -.071 .089 1.000 -.023 .003 .135 FCF .045 .035 .017 .032 -.195 .028 -.037 -.023 1.000 .026 -.087 INTA -.082 -.055 .065 -.077 .033 .066 .014 .003 .026 1.000 .049 NDTS .001 .028 -.026 .000 .005 -.141 -.030 .135 -.087 .049 1.000 Significant at the 0.01 level 2-tailed Significant at the 0.05 level 2-tailed The SIZE and MSO variables are also negatively correlated significantly - 0.158. This statistic confirms the wealth constraint argument, which suggests that the personal wealth constraint of corporate insiders is one important barrier to managerial share ownership. Specifically, as the size of the firm increases, it becomes more costly for managers to purchase a larger percentage of shares. A significant negative correlation between GROWTH and EBO - 0.161 is also found. This implies that the existence of external block holders reduces the firms‘ opportunity to use profit or earnings as retained earnings or expanding funds. A significantly negative correlation between INDUSTRY and NDTS -0.141 suggests that certain industries do not use annual depreciation expense as a mode to receive lower tax benefits and it could also explain the fiscal policy in East Asian countries on non-debt tax shield policy. Finally, PROF and NDTS also have a significant positive correlation 0.135 which implies that profitable firms are more likely to allocate its earnings to get free cash flow in form of annual depreciation expense. In order to test whether the external block ownership affect companies‘ capital structure, the study run a multivariate regression model that puts firm‘s debt to equity ratio as dependent variable. Table 6 presents the regression results for the external block ownership test that is, Model I. As can be seen from this table, there is supportive evidence of a positive relation between external block ownership and leverage. The coefficient on the EBO variable is positive and statistically significant t = 2.799. This positive relation is consistent with the active monitoring hypothesis that suggests that large shareholders have greater incentives to monitor management due to their significant investment in the firm. The increased monitoring by external block holders decreases managerial opportunism, leading to lower agency conflicts. The results obtained are also consistent with those of Friend and Lang 1988 who obtain evidence that firms with large non-managerial investors have significantly higher average debt ratios than those without external block holders. It does not support the passive voting hypothesis Pound, 1988 which suggests that large shareholders vote with management without due regard to the interests of dispersed shareholders. The overall regression explains approximately 20 of the variation in the dependent variable. Consistent with the size argument, the SIZE variable in the regression has a significant positive coefficient t-statistic = 6.358, suggesting that larger firms have higher leverage. This is consistent with Scott and Martin 1975 and Ferri and Jones 1979 and empirical evidence obtained by Agrawal and Nagarajan 1990. 157 Table 6: The Effect Of External Block Ownership On Capital Structure Model I Variable Coefficient T-Statistic Significance Constant -2.277 -8.970 .000 EBO .609 2.799 .005 SIZE .233 6.358 .000 Industry -.266 -2.412 .016 GrowthTA -.002 -1.925 .055 PROF -2.801 -6.333 .000 FCF 4.69E-005 .250 .802 INTA .240 .332 .740 NDTS -2.434 -1.281 .201 MODEL F value = 14.71 4.88 Adjusted R 2 = 0.200 = significant at α level = 1 t2.575 or t-2.575 = significant at α level = 5 t1.959 or t- 1.959 = significant at α level = 10 t1.644 or t- 1.644 The significant negative coefficient on PROF t-statistic = -6.333 is consistent with the pecking order hypothesis of Myers 1977 and Myers and Majluf 1984, and the empirical results of Titman and Wessels 1988, Friend and Lang 1988, Chiarella et al 1992, Allen 1993 and Wald 1995. The ―pecking order‖ hypothesis suggests that profitable firms will demand less debt because internal funds are available for financing projects. The IND variable which proxies for firm risk has a positive and significant coefficient t-statistic = -2.412. This is consistent with Scott and Martin 1975 and Bradley et al. 1984. It also suggests that resource companies have higher leverage than industrial companies in term of East Asian companies‘ characteristic that mainly operate in exploiting natural resources. The coefficient on the GROWTH variable is negative and marginally significant t-statistic = -1.925. This is consistent with Bradley et al. 1984 and Titman and Wessels 1988 who obtain a significant negative relationship between growth opportunities and firm‘s leverage. The unanticipated negative but insignificant coefficient on FCF may be due to the fact that the independent variables included in the models overlap and capture more than one effect. In this case, a few variables may proxy for the effect of free cash flow simultaneously. In particular, besides capturing the profitability effect, PROF variable may also proxy for the effect of free cash flow. To the extent that some industries have significant potential for free cash flow abuse, the IND variable may also capture some of the free cash flow effects. As a result, the FCF variable may only reflect the residual effects of free cash flow, as Brailsford et al. 2002 argued it. The coefficient on the NDTS variable is not significant. This supports the tax neutrality of capital structure under an imputation tax system.

2. The effect of managerial share ownership on financing decision