Discussion of results Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Energy Economics:Vol23.Issue2.2001:

G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191᎐210 201 emission estimates as well as an approximation of environmental degradation like deforestation. The EKC concept is dependent on the state of the economic activity. The main explanatory variable is the per capita income. As population grows and economic growth takes off, forests are being cut to provide materials for construction, land Ž for cultivation, etc. Usually, the larger the size of economic activity approximated . by GDP per capita the larger is the depletion of natural resources. By the laws of thermodynamics the use of natural resources implies the production of waste. The EKC literature assumes that there are no limits to growth. Income per capita represents consumer’s purchasing power and approximates the consumption patterns. We accompany income per capita with population density as explanatory variables to capture both scale and composition of consump- tion activities. We also consider the importance of some variables like the distribu- tion of GDP in manufacturing in order to examine the importance of specific sources of pollution in the analysis. We also take into consideration some other socio-economic variables to see their influence in this kind of analysis. Finally, dealing with the long-run character of CO emissions we include in the regressors 2 the growth rate of the economies of the countries under examination. Thus, we have used the following variables: GDP per capita in purchasing power Ž . Ž . parity million , 1991 ; the average annual growth rate of GDP in 1980᎐1991; Ž . Ž population density 1993, per 1000 hectares ; infant mortality rate per 1000 live . Ž . births in 1990᎐1995 ; urban population of total, 1995 ; distribution of GDP in Ž . Ž . manufacturing , 1991 ; deforestation average change, 1980᎐1990 ; and CO 2 Ž . per capita emissions in tons . The source of the last variable is Rodenburg et al. Ž . Ž 1995 while the rest of the variables were obtained from World Resources WRI, . 1991, 1994 . Frequency distributions for the main variables of the study are reported in Fig. 1. 3

6. Discussion of results

6.1. Separating hyperplane model 6.1.1. Magnitudes of ␤ and ␤ y ␤ 1 2 1 Ž . In the deforestation model estimates of ␤ are y0.429 and y0.469 see Table 1 1 for the normal and Student’s t, respectively, i.e. higher GNPrc leads to lower deforestation. The estimate of ␤ y ␤ is not statistically significant thus the two 2 1 3 The countries considered in our study are: Ethiopia, Mozambique, Bangladesh, Madagascar, Zambia, Uganda, Niger, Benin, India, Kenya, Pakistan, Nigeria, Ghana, Sri Lanka, Indonesia, Senegal, Zimbabwe, Philippines, Morocco, Dominican R., Honduras, Thailand, El Salvador, Nicaragua, Guate- mala, Cameroon, Jamaica, Paraguay, Botswana, Ecuador, Tunisia, Colombia, Chile, Peru, Mexico, Brazil, Panama, Hungary, Algeria, Portugal, Venezuela, Greece, Spain, Ireland, Singapore, former Czechoslovakia, UK, Italy, Australia, Belgium, the Netherlands, Austria, France, Germany, Finland, Denmark, Canada, Japan, Norway, USA and Switzerland. G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191᎐210 202 Fig. 1. Frequency distributions for main variables of the study. regimes are not different in terms of coefficients. In the CO model the estimates 2 of ␤ are 1.078 and 0.992, respectively. Again ␤ y ␤ is not significant. This can 1 2 1 be seen also from 95 Bayes probability intervals for ␥ . They are, generally, very 5 dispersed and do include the origin. We conclude that the two regimes do not differ in terms of ␤ and ␤ . 1 2 G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191᎐210 203 Table 1 a Posterior results for the SHSR Parameters Dependent variables Deforestation CO 2 Normal Student’s t Normal Student’s t ␤ y 0.43 y 0.47 1.07 0.99 1 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.23 0.25 0.14 0.17 ␤ y ␤ y 0.20 y 0.08 y 0.25 y 0.097 2 1 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.46 0.47 0.22 0.3 ␥ y 0.12 y 0.39 3.19 y 0.58 1 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 3.44 3.56 6.84 7.6 ␥ 0.4 0.31 y 8.66 y 3.04 2 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 4.36 4.21 8.73 11.7 ␥ 1.98 0.42 y 0.47 0.053 3 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 5.42 5.27 6.61 6.58 ␥ 0.16 y 0.32 y 4.38 y 1.47 4 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 3.42 3.49 6.67 7.49 ␥ 1.67 0.93 y 3.73 y 1.18 5 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 4.66 4.52 5.76 7.47 ␴ y 0.88 y 0.87 0.48 0.43 1 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.20 0.23 0.09 0.11 ␴ y ␴ 1.83 0.59 y 0.81 y 0.82 2 1 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.18 1.02 0.083 0.09 a Ž . Notes . Student’s t has 1 d.f. i.e. ␯ s 1 . Posterior standard deviations in parentheses. 6.1.2. Magnitudes of ␴ and ␴ y ␴ 1 2 1 In the deforestation case the difference ␴ y ␴ is 1.833 and 0.592 for the 2 1 normal and Student’s t models with S.E.s 0.175 and 1.016. Thus according to the normal specification ␴ ␴ but not according to the Student’s t specification. In 1 2 the CO model the variance differences are y0.807 and y0.815 with S.E.s 0.083 2 and 0.086, respectively, i.e. highly significant. Thus we may conclude that the two regimes differ in terms of error ¨ ariances of the en ¨ ironmental degradation equation. This means that the variances of deforestation or CO equations are different 2 and therefore policy changes, which affect GNP will not have the same result in high-income and low-income countries because of the different variances. When we use CO as the dependent variable we find that ␴ ␴ so low-income 2 1 2 countries have higher dispersion. Therefore policy measures which increase GNP will decrease CO emissions with higher certainty in high-income countries. The 2 opposite is true if we use deforestation as a dependent variable. 6.1.3. Magnitudes of ␥ . . . ␥ separating hyperplane coefficients 1 5 As can be seen from their posterior means and posterior standard errors none of Ž . the regressors urbanization, industrialization, mortality, growth or GNP appears Ž to be a separator. The sign of ␥ the coefficient of GNP in the separating 5 . hyperplane is positive when we consider the deforestation equation and negative when we consider the CO equation although statistically insignificant in both 2 G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191᎐210 204 cases. In this sense there is no e ¨ idence to support separation according to GNP or other economic and demographic ¨ ariables, which implies no support for an EKC. 6.1.4. Discussion of country membership to regimes We found that the two regimes are different in terms of ␴ 2 although this cannot 1 be explained by economic and demographic variables. Due to the fact that estimates of ␥ appear to be insignificant, allocating countries to the two regimes i according to the separating hyperplane should be viewed with conservatism. However, it is useful to compare separation probabilities across models and across dependent variables. 6.1.5. Discussion of differences between normal and Student’s t specifications Fig. 2a,b presents graphs of the probability of regime 2 for the Student’s t vs. the normal specification, using deforestation and CO as dependent variables, respec- 2 tively. Fig. 2c,d plots the same probability for CO vs. deforestation for the 2 Student’s t and normal distributions, respectively. From Fig. 2a,b, we see that Student’s t and normal distributions give comparable results only for CO . For 2 deforestation, there is significant disagreement in the separation probabilities ᎏ although they tend to be positively correlated, and strongly so under the Student’s t specification. Fig. 2c,d reveals significant divergence in the separation properties of different Ž . dependent variables. Under a normal specification Fig. 2c probabilities of regime 2 for CO and deforestation, show significant scattering around their regression 2 line. Under a Student’s t specification not only that happens but they also tend to be negatively correlated. Therefore it seems that not only the choice of dependent variable, but also the stochastic specification of switching regression models, affects separation significantly according to environmental degradation and economic᎐ demographic factors. Thus applied researchers who venture into testing for the existence of an EKC, should not only examine alternative dependent variables and alternative sets of regressors, but they should also examine different stochastic specifications for their switching regime or linear regression models. This adds another dimension of model uncertainty, yet it is necessary practice because EKCs are sensitive to all these factors. To put things in a different manner, given the choice of dependent and explanatory variables, EKCs will be sensiti ¨ e to alternative distributional assumptions about the error term. 4 In cross-sectional studies, this is something that applied researchers should expect, and therefore they should properly account for it in order to avoid excess sensitivity of results to the nature of the disturbance term. 6.2. Exogenous break model The most striking result that emerges from the exogenous break model is our 4 Distributional assumptions are important. This is the case in that logs vs. levels or fixed effects vs. random effects can have an impact on the results in panel regression studies. G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191 ᎐ 210 205 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . Fig. 2. Probabilities of regime 2: a deforestation; b CO ; c normal distribution; and d Student’s t. 2 G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191᎐210 206 Table 2 a Ž . Posterior results for the EBSR dependent variable: deforestation Explanatory Regime 1 Regime 2 Difference variables coefficients coefficients Constant 8.16 0.220 7.94 Ž . Ž . Ž . 2.40 9.81 9.98 Urbanization y 0.00038 y 0.0084 0.008 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.014 0.016 0.02 Industrialization 0.00086 0.015 y 0.14 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.016 0.047 0.051 Mortality y 0.018 0.162 y 0.180 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.0086 0.246 0.246 Growth y 0.080 0.180 y 0.260 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.088 0.389 0.403 log GNP y 0.843 y 0.181 y 0.662 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.345 1.007 1.049 2 ␴ 1.24 0.202 1.037 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.27 0.48 0.572 a Posterior standard deviations in parentheses. failure to find a posterior mean for the break z U significantly lower than the Ž . U maximum value of z i.e. log GNPrc in our specification . Estimates of z are 9.418 and 9.453 with posterior S.E.s 0.572 and 0.430 for deforestation and CO 2 equations, respectively. These are approximately 94 of the maximum value of log GNPrc. Moreover, the differences of ␤ y ␤ appear to be insignificant. The 1 i 2 i 2 2 Ž same is true for the difference ␴ y ␴ estimates are 1.037 and 0.217 with S.E.s 2 1 . 0.572 and 0.43, respectively ᎏ see Tables 2 and 3 . Thus, we find no e ¨ idence for a structural break from log GNP r c. For the deforestation model, mortality rates and log GNPrc are significant in the first regime but none of the variables is statistically significant in the second regime. For the CO model only industrialization and log GNPrc are significant in 2 the first regime. Notice that higher GNP implies lower deforestation in the first regime but higher CO emissions. We conclude that measuring en ¨ ironmental 2 degradation using deforestation or CO makes a difference. 2 Only for the deforestation model we find that ␴ 2 y ␴ 2 is close to significance 2 1 Ž . 1.037 and with S.E. 0.572 . So it turns out that we find very little evidence to support the existence of two regimes with differences in coefficients andror error variances. 6.2.1. Marginal posterior distribution of z U Marginal posterior distributions of z U for the deforestation and CO model are 2 shown in Fig. 3. From inspection it follows that the mass is concentrated between 90 and 95 of the maximum value of z s log GNP. It is remarkable that for G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191᎐210 207 Table 3 a Ž . Posterior results for the EBSR dependent variable: CO 2 Explanatory Regime 1 Regime 2 Difference variables coefficients coefficients Constant y 6.23 6.02 y 12.25 Ž . Ž . Ž . 1.34 14.33 14.31 Urbanization 0.0063 0.0076 y 0.0013 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.007 0.0203 0.0217 Industrialization 0.025 y 0.022 0.048 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.009 0.045 0.045 Mortality y 0.0057 0.362 y 0.368 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.0049 0.278 0.28 Growth 0.0448 0.434 y 0.389 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.050 0.365 0.369 log GNP 0.771 y 0.731 1.502 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.185 1.468 1.467 2 ␴ 0.406 0.188 0.217 Ž . Ž . Ž . 0.09 0.418 0.430 a Posterior standard deviations in parentheses. both the log CO and deforestation models these distributions are approximately 2 the same. Ž . Fig. 3. Posteriors of break point relative to maximum log GNP . G.E. Halkos, E.G. Tsionas r Energy Economics 23 2001 191᎐210 208

7. Concluding remarks