Sources of partial adjustment

L. Coppock, M. Poitras International Review of Economics and Finance 9 2000 181–192 185 The BI technique defines the weights according to [Eq. 3] w i 5 min {1, at i }, 3 where a is a constant chosen to set the bound on the influence, and t i is a measure of the influence of observation i. 13 The two-step Welsch and iterative Krasker-Welsch techniques use somewhat different methods to measure the influence, t i . In either case, however, the definition of t i consists of a quadratic function dx i of the explana- tory variables that measures the “leverage” of observation i, multiplied by a standard- ized measure of the estimated residual for observation i. Thus, we have [Eq. 4] 14 t i 5 dx i |y i 2 x i bˆs|. 4 The two-step procedure performs OLS in the first stage and weighted least squares in the second stage. The Krasker-Welsch iterative procedure updates the estimates of b, w i , and s at each step. The procedure converges to a unique solution, and the resulting estimator is consistent and asymptotically normal. The Krasker-Welsch estimator is also asymptotically efficient among BI estimators, given that an efficient BI estimator exists. 15 The BI technique does not provide a panacea for all possible econometric pathologies, but the method does yield inferences robust to small sample changes and likely mitigates the effects of omitted variables and data reporting errors. Given the size of our sample, the BI technique insures that any subsample of meaning- ful size should yield essentially the same inferences. Columns III and IV of Table 1 display BI estimates of Eq. 1. In contrast to the OLS results, the BI estimates of b lie significantly below one at the .01 level, indicating rejection of the Fisher hypothesis. The rejection is especially strong in light of the fact that full adjustment with interest taxation implies b greater than one. The results contradict those of Duck 1993, and demonstrate the importance of bounding the influence of the outliers in these data. While the results do not support a point-for- point Fisher effect, the estimates do indicate a significant partial effect. 16 Table 2 lists the downweighted observations and the values of the weights, w i , for the squared residuals. The two techniques can generate different weights because they define the influence differently. Note that the set of downweighted observations almost exclusively includes high-inflation countries; the two-step procedure down- weights five of the six highest-inflation observations, and the iterative procedure downweights six of the nine highest. In particular, both methods strongly downweight Brazil, suggesting that this observation does not conform to the same empirical model as do the bulk of the data. In the following section we present a brief discussion of some leading theoretical explanations for the failure to observe a full Fisher effect. We then extend the empirical model to examine a theory that attributes the source of partial adjustment to the liquidity properties of financial assets.

4. Sources of partial adjustment

As a theoretical proposition, the Fisher effect has considerable intuitive appeal. Researchers, however, cite several theories that can seemingly undermine the effect, 186 L. Coppock, M. Poitras International Review of Economics and Finance 9 2000 181–192 Table 2 Downweighted observations a Eq. 1 Eq. 5 Inflation Country rank Two-step Krasker-Welsch Two-step Krasker-Welsch Brazil 1 0.04 0.01 0.03 0.02 Bolivia 2 0.03 1.00 0.03 1.00 Peru 3 0.16 1.00 0.06 0.06 Turkey 4 1.00 0.27 1.00 1.00 Iceland 5 0.61 0.93 1.00 1.00 Ecuador 6 0.87 0.27 NA NA Columbia 7 1.00 0.19 1.00 0.34 Greece 9 1.00 0.85 1.00 1.00 Spain 14 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.71 Trinidad Tobago 17 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.73 Guatemala 18 1.00 0.69 NA NA Denmark 29 1.00 0.97 1.00 1.00 Switzerland 39 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.99 a Countries are ranked from highest 1 to lowest 40 level of inflation. The weights are those assigned to the squared residuals in least squares estimation. even in the long-run. A number of authors invoke money illusion, but this explanation conflicts with the fundamental rationality assumption of modern theory. Some hypoth- eses consistent with rationality state that inflation systematically reduces the real interest rate. Most frequently cited is the Mundell-Tobin effect, whereby inflation causes substitution of capital for money, and the resulting increase in the capital stock reduces the real rate. The Mundell-Tobin effect, however, seems unlikely to have an empirically significant effect on interest rates. Summers 1983 calculates that since money holding amounts to less than 2 of the value of the capital stock, substitution of capital for money can reduce the real rate by no more than about 6 basis points. Another explanation for partial adjustment, the so-called Wicksell effect, maintains that redistribution caused by monetary expansion systematically reduces the real rate Wicksell, 1907; Cagan, 1980. Our calculations indicate that, like the Mundell-Tobin effect, the Wicksell effect cannot account for significant reductions in real rates because of the relatively large size of the existing capital stock. A more plausible explanation uses the idea that low-risk financial assets such as government bonds yield non-pecuniary liquidity returns. Fried and Howitt 1983 show that if money and bonds substitute in the production of liquidity, and each offers positive but diminishing marginal liquidity, then inflation-induced substitution of bonds for money increases the liquidity premium on bonds and lowers the pecuniary real rate. Hence, the Fried-Howitt effect implies that the Fisher effect might hold for illiquid, but not liquid, assets. The result has implications for cross-country tests of the Fisher effect since the liquidity of government bonds varies across countries. U.S. Treasury securities have immense trading volume and are thus highly liquid, but sovereign debt issues of many nations trade in relatively thin markets and might lack L. Coppock, M. Poitras International Review of Economics and Finance 9 2000 181–192 187 Table 3 Estimates of Eq. 5 I II III IV Variable OLS OLS, omit Brazil Two-step BI Krasker-Welsch BI Inflation 1.18 0.737 1.04 0.961 0.10 0.070 0.10 0.095 Inflation 20.427 20.178 20.366 20.316 Variance 0.097 0.055 0.152 0.068 Grade 7.67 1.72 5.17 4.51 2.99 1.63 1.68 1.59 Grade · inflation 20.528 20.151 20.399 20.332 0.177 0.097 0.106 0.102 Intercept 20.85 4.83 1.58 2.20 2.44 1.37 1.45 1.38 R 2 0.899 0.925 0.872 0.929 Rw i 35 34 32.12 31.85 Parentheses contain standard errors. The reported R 2 applies to the weighted dependent variable. Indicates significant difference from zero at the 0.01 level. Indicates significant difference from zero at the 0.05 level. liquidity. In some nations, precious metals or U.S. dollar-denominated assets might supersede sovereign debt as a substitute for money balances in times of inflation. To control for liquidity differences, we define a dummy variable GRADE taking the value 1 for countries with Moody’s bond risk ratings of investment grade Baa or higher and zero otherwise. Strictly speaking, risk and liquidity are not identical; nonetheless, sovereign risk ratings should provide a useful proxy since low risk typically characterizes highly liquid assets. The extended empirical model takes the form r i 5 a 1 b p i 1 b 1 VP i 1 b 2 GRADE i 1 b 3 GRADE · p i 1 e t . 5 To allow for a Fried-Howitt effect, the interaction term GRADE · p i permits the marginal effect of inflation on investment grade debt, b 1 b 3 , to differ from that on non-investment grade debt, b . The specification also includes the dummy variable GRADE to permit a fixed effect, b 2 , of risk or liquidity on yields. Table 3 displays estimates of Eq. 5. 17 The estimates indicate a significant shift in the marginal effect of inflation across bond grade categories. The OLS estimates in column I suggest that the marginal effect falls short of one for investment grade sovereigns, and exceeds one for non-investment grade sovereigns. As column II shows, however, dropping the Brazil observation again causes a considerable reorientation of the estimated regression. In response, we obtain BI estimates of Eq. 5. Columns III and IV show that the point estimate of the marginal effect of inflation for non- investment grade sovereigns lies remarkably close to one for both the two-step and iterative BI techniques. In contrast, the point estimates of 0.64 and 0.63 for investment grade bonds lie significantly below one at the 0.01 level. The result suggests rejection 188 L. Coppock, M. Poitras International Review of Economics and Finance 9 2000 181–192 of the hypothesis of a full Fisher effect for liquid, but not illiquid, sovereigns, which concurs with the Fried-Howitt hypothesis. 18

5. Conclusions

Dokumen yang terkait

Relationship of Family Support Towards Self-Management and Quality of Life of Patients with Type 2 Diabetes Mellitus

0 0 8

Comparison of Mirror and Video Methods in Increasing Caregiver Knowledge in Treating Clients Halusination

0 0 9

Relationship between Age, Gender, and Peer Group with Reproductive Healthy Behavior of Teen

0 0 9

The Effect of Parent Distraction Coaching Used The Toy on Pain Intensity of 1–5 Year-Old Children during Iv (Intravenous) Insertion

0 0 11

The Distinction of Inhibiting Factors among Patients who Actively and Inactively Participate in Phase II Cardiac Rehabilitation

0 0 11

Time Value of Money Perspektif Syariah

0 1 14

197 ZIRAA’AH, Volume 35 Nomor 3, Oktober 2012 Halaman 197-203 ISSN 1412-1468 RESPON BEBERAPA VARIETAS MENTIMUN (Cucumis sativus L.) TERHADAP PEMBERIAN AIR KELAPA TUA (Respons Several of Cucumber (Cucumis sativus L.) Varieties on the Towards of Ripe Coconu

0 0 7

PERANAN KELOMPOK TANI DALAM MENGEMBANGKAN KEMANDIRIAN PETANI DI KABUPATEN TANA TIDUNG (The Frame of Farmer Groups Empowerment Towards Self-reliance of Farmer in Tana Tidung District) Midiansyah Effendi Program Studi Agribisnis Fakultas Pertanian Universit

0 0 13

Key words :forward and backward, planting season, time of planting PENDAHULUAN - Penentuan Musim Tanam dan Waktu Tanam Padi Sawah Berdasarkan Akumulasi Curah Hujan Sepuluh Hari Hitung Maju dan Mundur di Kelurahan Lempake Kota Samarinda

0 0 8

PRESENTASE JENIS MAKANAN DALAM LAMBUNG IKAN LAIS (Ompok hypopthalmus) DI RAWA SUNGAI RUNGAN, KOTA PALANGKA RAYA (Feed Type Percentage In The Stomach of Fish Lais (Ompok hypophthalmus) In Rungan Swamp River, Palangka Raya City) Lukas dan Infa Minggawati Pr

0 0 5