Private rates of return to education Summary of results and conclusions

297 H.K. Siphambe Economics of Education Review 19 2000 291–300 Table 8 Basic Mincerian earnings function by sector of employment — corrected for choice of employment SS Data a Variable Public sector Private sector Parastatals Constant 6.4 24 4.9 45.08 7.8 14. Education 0.09 7.8 0.09 7 0.08 5.1 Experience 0.028 2.5 0.07 5.5 0.057 2.5 Experience square 20.00023 20.6 20.0013 22.5 20.00077 21.09 Inverse Mills Ratio 20.6 24.9 0.47 2.8 21.2 24.1 R 2 adjusted 0.57 0.36 0.64 N 276 499 79 a Values in parentheses are t-statistics. Asterisks indicate level of significance: , 1 level; , 5 level. variable is significant at the 1 level for all three sectors. 9

7. Private rates of return to education

Table 9 summarises the results of a Mincerian earn- ings function that has education as a non-continuous variable. We now have 1–0 dummies for the five school- ing cycles. 10 All coefficients are significant at the 1 Table 9 Earnings function with schooling cycles dummies — corrected for censoring bias HIES a Variable All Constant 5.07 35.8 Primary 0.4 9.7 Lower secondary 1.1 23.3 High secondary 1.9 28.8 Tertiary 2.1 21.9 Experience 0.057 7.7 Experience square 20.00095 27.4 Inverse Mills Ratio 20.78 26.6 R 2 adjusted 0.44 Sample size N 2891 a Values in parentheses are t-statistics. , Significant at 1 level. 9 Refer to Appendix A, Table A2, for probit results for choice between sectors of employment. 10 Primary education takes 7 years, lower secondary 3 years, upper secondary 2 years and university 4 years, except for a Degree in Law. level and have the right signs. Table 10 is a summary of the private rates of return to the different schooling cycles, which are derived from Table 9. The rate of return is highest for upper secondary 185, then lower secondary 84 and lowest for primary education 7.

8. Summary of results and conclusions

The general results from the previous analysis are that the rates of return to education do not decline by level of education. They are highest for upper secondary edu- cation, and lowest for primary education. The general trend, based mainly on Latin American countries and the aggregate ones reported by Psacharopoulos, is for the rates of return to be highest for primary followed by sec- ondary and lowest for tertiary education. Our results also show that the rates of return to the two secondary school education cycles are quite distinct. Higher secondary education has higher private rates of return than lower secondary. The rates of return to education figures from this study, particularly for primary education, are quite low compared with those estimated by the USAID 1984 study. It is evident therefore that private rates of return to education have been declining, especially for lower secondary and primary education cycles. The falling rates are quite expected given the dramatically changing Table 10 Annual private rate of return to schooling for each schooling cycle with dummies a Education Primary Lower Upper Tertiary level secondary secondary Rate of 7 83 185 38 return a Source: Based on Table 9. 298 H.K. Siphambe Economics of Education Review 19 2000 291–300 labour market conditions, particularly on the supply side. There was a significant increase in the supply of gradu- ates as proxied by total student enrolment to the labour market, while job opportunities rose less fast. In other words, the rate of employment creation was not adequate to absorb all the graduates entering the labour market. The latest figure on unemployment is estimated at 21 and is highest for those under 25 years of age. It is also highest for those with 1–3 years of secondary education, followed by those with primary education Republic of Botswana, 1996. The result of this mismatch between supply and demand for labour was that competition for the few available jobs became intense. The competition created more demand for education at all levels. The labour mar- ket responded to the increases in supply of graduates by escalating minimum job requirements. The result is that school leavers are filtering down occupation hierarchies. For instance, jobs that were previously the preserve of illiterates and primary school graduates are now com- peted for by secondary school graduates. Although rates of return are generally low, primary education is the most affected. These rates are low because the earnings differentials between workers with primary education and those with no education are very small. Therefore, monetary benefits of going to primary school are very small. This is a result of a phenomenon which has already been discussed: that the primary school graduates were being pushed out of the labour market to very low-paying jobs including informal activities. There are of course some major non-monetary benefits to primary education, which this model does not capture; for instance political awareness, health, etc. Moreover, the benefits for primary education are cap- tured as benefits to other levels of education for those who go beyond primary education. While lower secondary expanded at a very fast pace, upper secondary education expanded at a relatively lower pace. About 30 or less of the lower secondary completers got places into upper secondary Republic of Botswana, 1993. It was this group of graduates who were obtaining an increasing share of the mainly skilled, middle level jobs that used to be the preserve of lower secondary school leavers. The additional cost of acquir- ing this privileged access to relatively few good job openings was usually only 2 more years of full time edu- cation. The net income benefits as shown by the earn- ings differential between this group and the lower sec- ondary school have been quite high. Tertiary education has also been highly profitable, as shown in the results from the HIES data. This is mainly due to high earnings compared to earnings of those with upper secondary education level. Generally rates of return to education increase by level of education. Apart from the changes in the labour mar- ket that have already been discussed, these results may have other major implications about education. First, that more able people obtain more schooling. The higher rates for higher levels will therefore be a result of higher ability. Second, that quality of education may be improv- ing as one moves up the education ladder. However, this study does not measure changes in school quality and ability differences. Therefore, it is not possible to be pre- cise about the changes in ability and school quality. A more important issue arising from these results is that the British-type of schooling usually contains a strong filtering and screening mechanism through which more able students, or students from households at the higher end of the income distribution, transit up the educational hierarchy. Guisinger, Henderson and Scully 1984 make a similar point about the positive relationship between rates of return and level of education for Pakistan. Finally, education in Botswana appears to exacerbate income inequalities. The high rate of return for higher levels of education indicate that the distance between the earnings of the highest and lowest worker in the skill hierarchy is large, which may be one reason why Bots- wana has such a high income inequality. 11

9. Policy implications