Results Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Energy Economics:Vol22.Issue3.2000:

R.M. Shrestha r Energy Economics 22 2000 297]308 300 Ž . Ž . where, L l ,l and L l ,l are the maximum likelihood ratio values of the 1 2 UR 1 2 R unrestricted and restricted models, respectively.

3. Data and their sources

Cross-sectional data from 1988 to 1990 for 41 countries were used in the estimation of output]energy relationship with GNP and GDP as output ME R PPP measures while the data set involving GDP was smaller and involved 31 ME R countries only as GDP data for some countries were obviously questionable ME R and were therefore excluded. The countries included in this study are listed in Appendix A. Data on GNP per capita and GDP per capita were obtained from UNDP ME R PPP Ž . Ž . 1991, 1992, 1993 while data on GDP were taken from IMF 1993 . The source ME R Ž for per capita commercial energy consumption data was World Bank 1990, 1991, . 1992 . Traditional energy consumption data for 1989 were obtained from WRI Ž . 1992 .

4. Results

4.1. Effects of using alternati ¨ e output measures Ž Tables 1]3 present the maximum likelihood estimates of parameters a , b, l , 1 . l of the generalized Box]Cox model along with the ordinary least squares 2 estimates of parameters a and b of double-log, semi-log and linear models when the output is measured by GNP , GDP and GDP , respectively. The ME R MER PPP tables also show the associated values of R 2 , the maximum of log likelihood w Ž .x 2 w function i.e. L l , l and the calculated values of x test statistic as defined in 1 2 Ž .x 2 Eq. 5 . Note that R values across the models here are not directly comparable as the dependent variables are not the same for each model. Following Kennedy Ž . Ž . 2 1992, p. 102 and Gujarati 1995, pp. 209]210 , we have also calculated R values Ž . Ž . for Models 1 and 4 in a manner that makes them comparable to the values Ž . Ž . 1 calculated by Models 2 and 3 . These are also presented in the tables. As can be seen from the tables, of the three restricted models considered, the calculated values of x 2 statistic in the case of the double-log model were less than Ž . the critical value at the 5 significance level i.e. 5.991 for sample data of each of Ž . 2 the 3 years considered i.e. 1988, 1989, and 1990 . However, the calculated x values were greater than the critical values at both 5 and 1 levels for both linear and semi-log models. Thus, the double-log model could not be rejected 1 The following procedure was used in the derivation of the comparable value of R 2 . First, the estimated ˆ ˆ Ž . Ž . values of Y i.e. Y from the ‘optimal’ i.e. Box]Cox and linear models are converted into ln Y . Then i i i 2 ˆ R between ln Y and ln Y is computed for each of these models. i i R.M. Shrestha r Energy Economics 22 2000 297]308 301 Table 1 a Estimates of parameters of output]energy relationship with GNP as the output measure ME R 2 2 b 2 Ž . Ž . Model a b l l R R L l ,l x 1 2 1 2 2 1988 c Optimal 0.721 0.959 0.059 0.088 0.880 0.880 y 364.381 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 3.760 0.860 0.096 0.128 Double-log 0.033 1.120 0.879 0.879 y 364.765 0.768 Ž . Ž . 0.492 0.066 Semi-log 7.070 0.00044 1 0.668 0.668 y 385.518 42.274 Ž . Ž . 0.181 0.00005 Linear 1050.0 2.580 1 1 0.696 0.722 y 401.0 73.238 Ž . Ž . 987.0 0.273 1989 c Optimal 1.40 0.769 0.024 0.081 0.860 0.861 y 372.064 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 3.360 0.778 0.100 0.158 Double-log y 0.054 1.140 0.859 0.859 y 372.325 0.522 Ž . Ž . 0.549 0.074 Semi-log 7.110 0.00045 1 0.659 0.659 y 390.395 36.662 Ž . Ž . 0.190 0.000052 Linear 1180.0 2.80 1 1 0.658 0.681 y 408.0 71.872 Ž . Ž . 1190.0 0.323 1990 c Optimal 0.903 0.901 0.041 0.081 0.858 0.858 y 376.309 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 3.920 0.901 0.104 0.160 Double-log y 0.115 1.150 0.857 0.857 y 376.576 0.534 Ž . Ž . 0.564 0.075 Semi-log 7.190 0.00045 1 0.651 0.651 y 394.870 37.122 Ž . Ž . 0.194 0.000053 Linear 1360.0 3.030 1 1 0.651 0.662 y 412.0 71.382 Ž . Ž . 1300.0 0.355 a Figures inside parentheses represent standard errors of the estimated parameters. b These figures represent the values of R 2 that are comparable to those of double and semi-log Ž . models i.e. with log Y as the dependent variable . c ‘Optimal’ here refers to the Box]Cox model. irrespective of the output measures considered while both the linear and semi-log models were rejected. Ž . The estimated coefficient of energy consumption per capita i.e. b for the double-log model with GNP as the output measure was found to range from ME R Ž . 1.12 to 1.15 all statistically significant at 5 . Note that the estimated values of b Ž . in Table 1 are higher than those reported by MSV i.e. 0.890]0.914 . The values of b with GDP as the output measure varied from 0.925 to 0.934 while those in ME R the case of GDP were in the range 0.614]0.658. ppp The hypothesis of non-diminishing returns to energy per capita was not rejected at the 5 significance level for all 3 years in the GNP case as in MSV. In the ME R GDP case, the hypothesis could not be rejected at the 5 significance level ME R R.M. Shrestha r Energy Economics 22 2000 297]308 302 Table 2 a Estimates of parameters of output]energy relationship with GDP as the output measure ME R 2 2 b 2 Ž . Ž . Model a b l l R R L l ,l x 1 2 1 2 2 1988 c Optimal y 1.050 1.700 0.123 0.055 0.950 0.950 y 258.463 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 5.190 1.290 0.128 0.129 Double-log 1.320 0.934 0.951 0.951 y 259.244 1.562 Ž . Ž . 0.297 0.039 Semi-log 7.120 0.00038 1 0.714 0.714 y 286.597 56.268 Ž . Ž . 0.180 0.000044 Linear 1030.0 1.830 1 1 0.853 0.869 y 280.0 43.074 Ž . Ž . 575.0 0.141 1989 c Optimal 0.097 1.380 0.081 0.034 0.937 0.939 y 263.039 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 4.450 1.230 0.132 0.148 Double-log 1.370 0.925 0.939 0.939 y 263.340 0.602 Ž . Ž . 0.333 0.044 Semi-log 7.120 0.00038 1 0.716 0.716 y 287.182 48.286 Ž . Ž . 0.182 0.000044 Linear 1040 1.820 1 1 0.825 0.860 y 283.0 39.922 Ž . Ž . 646.0 0.156 1990 c Optimal 0.013 1.400 0.084 0.036 0.933 0.935 y 264.484 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 4.550 1.240 0.122 0.144 Double-log 1.350 0.930 0.935 0.935 y 264.793 0.618 Ž . Ž . 0.347 0.046 Semi-log 7.150 0.00037 1 0.706 0.706 y 288.114 47.26 Ž . Ž . 0.184 0.000044 Linear 1130 1.82 1 1 0.810 0.847 y 285.0 41.032 Ž . Ž . 678.0 0.164 a Figures inside parentheses represent standard errors of the estimated parameters. b These figures represent the values of R 2 that are comparable to those of double and semi-log Ž . models i.e. with log Y as the dependent variable . c ‘Optimal’ here refers to the Box]Cox model. except with the data set of 1989. The hypothesis in this case was, however, rejected for all 3 years at the 10 significance level. Interestingly, in the GDP case, the hypothesis of non-decreasing output ppp returns to energy per capita was consistently rejected for all 3 years even at the 1 significance level. This is contrary to the finding of MSV in the GNP case. ME R Clearly, output returns to energy is found to be sensitive to the choice of the output measure. Note that for the reasons stated earlier, GDP is considered to PP P be a better measure of output for cross country studies and the present analysis shows the output returns to energy use to be diminishing when GDP is used as PP P the output measure. It may be interesting to ask why the estimated value of b in the GDP case is PP P R.M. Shrestha r Energy Economics 22 2000 297]308 303 Table 3 a Estimates of parameters of output]energy relationship with GDP as the output measure PP P 2 2 b 2 Ž . Ž . Model a b l l R R L l ,l x 1 2 1 2 2 1988 c Optimal 7.140 0.766 0.133 0.130 0.897 0.896 y 357.324 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 4.710 1.090 0.209 0.135 Double-log 4.250 0.614 0.894 0.894 y 358.027 1.404 Ž . Ž . 0.250 0.034 Semi-log 8.10 0.00025 1 0.703 0.703 y 379.233 43.816 Ž . Ž . 0.093 0.000026 Linear 3140.0 1.880 1 1 0.793 0.828 y 377.0 39.350 Ž . Ž . 554.0 0.154 1989 c Optimal 9.560 0.749 0.185 0.197 0.893 0.891 y 361.009 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 7.770 0.993 0.2 0.164 Double-log 4.240 0.620 0.886 0.886 y 362.478 2.938 Ž . Ž . 0.266 0.036 Semi-log 8.120 0.00025 1 0.723 0.723 y 380.635 39.252 Ž . Ž . 0.092 0.000025 Linear 3090.0 2.040 1 1 0.818 0.843 y 378.0 33.982 Ž . Ž . 566.0 0.154 1990 c Optimal 6.260 1.380 0.190 0.130 0.865 0.861 y 371.792 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 7.070 2.0 0.226 0.172 Double-log 4.040 0.658 0.862 0.862 y 372.632 1.680 Ž . Ž . 0.315 0.042 Semi-log 8.190 0.00026 1 0.665 0.665 y 390.780 37.976 Ž . Ž . 0.108 0.000029 Linear 3690.0 2.190 1 1 0.735 0.861 y 390.0 36.416 Ž . Ž . 775.0 0.211 a Figures inside parentheses represent standard errors of the estimated parameters. b These figures represent the values of R 2 that are comparable to those of double and semi-log Ž . models i.e. with log Y as the dependent variable . c ‘Optimal’ here refers to the Box]Cox model. less than that in the GDP case. In most low income developing countries which ME R are at the lower range of energy consumption per capita, the reported values of GDP are higher than the corresponding value of GNP while the opposite is PP P MER the case for most high income industrialized countries which have a higher level of Ž . energy consumption see Fig. 1 . Similar observations can be made between GDP and GDP cases. This indicates that, with other things remaining the PP P MER Ž . same, the estimated value of b with the ‘correct’ measure of output i.e. GDP PP P would be smaller than those in cases with GNP and GDP . ME R MER 4.2. Effects of inclusion of traditional energy consumption In the preceding analysis, like MSV, we considered only the use of commercial R.M. Shrestha r Energy Economics 22 2000 297 ] 308 304 Fig. 1. Output per capita vs. energy consumption per capita in 1990. R.M. Shrestha r Energy Economics 22 2000 297]308 305 Ž . i.e. ‘modern’ fuels in the energy input. However, it is well-known that unlike industrialized countries, developing countries have high dependence on traditional fuels. Although the data on traditional fuel consumption are far less reliable than Ž . the commercial energy data, especially in developing countries a study of output]energy relationship cannot totally ignore the use of traditional fuels given the latter’s importance in developing countries. In order to gain some insight into the order of magnitude of the effects of traditional fuel consumption, we estimated Ž . Ž . the parameters of Eqs. 1 ] 4 with the 1989 data of 31 countries by including the use of both commercial and traditional fuels in the input measure. The results are presented in Table 4. The log-linear model was again preferred to semi-log and linear models. The estimated values of b in GNP GDP and GDP cases ME R, MER PPP are 1.300, 1.060 and 0.711, respectively. Two observations are interesting to make: first, for each of the output measures considered, the estimated values of b are now consistently higher than the corresponding figures when only commercial fuels were included in energy consumption. Secondly, the hypothesis of increasing output returns to energy consumption is rejected even at the 1 significance level in the GDP case while it is not rejected in both GNP and GDP cases at PP P MER MER the 5 significance level. In other words, with correct measures of output and energy consumption, the results of this study give a strong indication that output per capita exhibits non-increasing returns to energy consumption contrary to the findings of MSV. 4.3. Robustness of the estimated parameters As in MSV, the stability of the estimated parameter values over the selected years in the study were examined using the Chow-test. The calculated values of F in the GNP , GDP and GDP cases are 0.2642, 0.0096 and 1.1485, 4,117 MER MER PPP respectively, well below the critical value of 2.45 at the 5 significance level. Thus, the hypothesis that the estimated values of parameters were robust over the years could not be rejected in any of the cases considered. As normality of residuals is w assumed in the Chow-test, it was examined through the Jarque]Bera test see e.g. Ž . x Ž Kmenta 1986 , pp. 265]267 . The values of the test statistic for this purpose which 2 . is x distributed for the data sets of 1988, 1989 and 1990 for each type of output 2 measure and commercial energy consumption are presented in Table 5. Note that 2 Ž 2 the calculated values of x are all - 5.991 i.e. the critical value of x at the 5 2 2 . significance level . Thus, the hypothesis of the normality of residuals could not be rejected for any of the data sets.

5. Conclusions and final remarks