could account for profitability differences, such as high startup costs in the US market. Attempting to defuse political pressures, the Chancellor of the Exchequer
John Major wrote to the Treasury Secretary Nicholas Brady proposing a joint multilateral study of tax avoidance by multinationals, an offer which Brady gratefully
accepted, along with a similar German proposal.
1
What was most striking was that neither the efforts by the US over three decades to develop an effective transfer price
regime for US foreign direct investments, nor the work in international bodies especially the OECD since 1975, were regarded as providing an adequate answer to
US political concerns about the adequacy of taxation of inward direct investment.
3. The Indeterminacy of Arms Length
The administration of transfer pricing rules under the Arms Length principle has faced two basic difficulties. First, it entails a focus on specific transactions; and
second, it relies on finding comparable transactions between unrelated parties. Underlying these is the basic problem that Arms Length depends on treating related
companies as if they were unrelated. The essential advantages of a corporate group are that fixed costs can be jointly shared, and that a successfully integrated firm
generates synergy profits, or additional returns attributable to the organization as a whole rather than any particular unit. The Arms Length approach based on
transactional analysis entails attempting to dissect this unity.
3.a Arms Length Price or Arms Length Profit
The Arms Length principle essentially requires adjustments to be made to the pricing of specific transactions rather than performing a global profit allocation.
Nevertheless, both tax administrators and courts have used the profit split produced by price adjustment as an important factor either in validating price adjustments, or
even to decide what the adjustment should be. Some have justified this by arguing that arms length merely requires affiliates to be treated as separate entities, and their
assessment to begin from separate accounts, and that the approach is not vitiated by using profit split as a check Hunter, in Competent Authorities 1986, p.594.
i Identification of Specific Transactions
The US regulations of 1968 were the first to establish a detailed approach to the identification of specific intrafirm transactions in which one affiliate is the supplier
of something to another. However, a supplierreceiver relationship may be hard to
1
Letter of 29 August, printed in Tax Notes of 10 September 1990.
define among related companies sharing factor inputs. It appears most clearly in the sale of tangibles, since there is a clear transfer of a physical item. The supply of
tangibles for use leasing may also appear to be a clear bilateral transaction, although there may frequently be shared use. A loan may also appear to be a clearly bilateral
relationship, but the common case of a parent company guarantee for a subsidiarys borrowing is not easy to classify. Most problems are caused by services and
intangibles, which commonly consist of activities carried out for the joint benefit of all or many of the companies in a corporate group. Thus, the US s.482 rules provide
detailed definitions to identify the `renderer
¶ of services, the `developer¶ of know how, and the beneficiary or recipient of each.
Further, a relationship which appears to involve a straightforward bilateral relationship may require more detailed analysis to define the various transactions
involved. Thus, one relationship may involve two or more transactions: a sale of tangibles such as the active ingredient for a drug often involves a simultaneous
transfer of intangibles, the rights to the patents embodied in it: therefore, `unbundling
¶ the different transactional elements may be important. Equally, a transaction may be reciprocal: a patent licence will commonly include a grantback
clause for development patents, which must be dealt with by provisions for setoffs.
ii ProfitSplit: Criterion or Check?
As the limitations of the transactional approach in the US Regulations have become more apparent, the use of profitsplit has gained ground. Initially, there was
uncertainty as to its validity: in Du Pont v. US, the trial judge stated critically that `the regulation approach seems to rule out net profit as a relevant consideration in the
determination of an arms length price, this despite Congress encouragement to the contrary
¶
1
However, the appeals court in the same case approved `consideration of net profits in appraising the realism of prices charged
¶Du Pont v. US 1979, p. 456. This seemed to make sense of the prior cases: in Lufkin Foundry 1972 the use of
profit split by the Tax Court had been overturned on appeal, on the ground that there had been no attempt first to find an arms length price; while in Pittsburgh Plate
Glass Industries Inc. 1970 a profit split analysis was used in support of the adjustment produced by a comparable. Finally, the courts went a stage further in Eli
Lilly v Commissioner 1988, in accepting an allocation based on profit split, after attempts to fix arms length prices had failed due to nonexistence of comparables.
2
A study of all the s.482 cases in the courts between 1962 and 1980 22 cases
± also
1
Judge Willi, in Du Pont v. US, cited in US Treasury 1988 p. 34.
2
In the meantime, Congress had enacted a new Tax Code provision, in response to this case, specifying that corporations with affiliates in US possessions i.e. Puerto Rico earning income from
intangibles must divide the income, either under a cost sharing method, or on the basis of a 5050 profit split: Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act 1982 s.213a, adding section 936h to the Tax
Code; see below.
confirmed the importance of profitsplit Donnelly 1986. The position thus reached in the US was that profit split is important as a check on the reasonableness of
adjustments to transaction prices; and it could also be used in its own right where adjustment based on arms length is not possible.
In practice, in most countries, it is more likely to be the taxpayer that relies on the arms length price criterion, by pointing to a market price which should be accepted
as comparable; while the main point of reference for the tax authorities will be the profit which the price produces. Although this means primarily a comparison with the
profits of other similar undertakings, inevitably there will also be some consideration of the internal profitsplit within the TNC. Thus, the French law of 1933 see s. 1.b
above already provided that, in the absence of specific data to establish an arms length price, the assessment may be done by comparison with the profits of similar
undertakings normally managed. Similarly, the Japanese law of 1986 states that if a company does not provide the information necessary to calculate the arms length
price, the local tax office may calculate a price based on the gross margin ratio on sales or some other appropriate ratio of a similar company in the same line of
business. A senior Japanese official has also indicated that profit split is likely to be used by administrators as a check on the `reasonableness
¶ of a price adjustment Competent Authorities 1986, p.591. Equally, the German law of 1972 s.13, as
amended in 1976 allows, in the absence of other appropriate criteria, an assessment based on the return on invested capital, or margin on turnover, which could be
expected under normal circumstances. The 1983 German regulations also specify that it is legitimate to compare the business results of the taxpayer, its related companies,
and other similar companies, either as a check on or an alternative to other methods of establishing arms length prices.
1
Although the UK statutory provisions only permit adjustments to the pricing of specific transactions, in practice the profit split produced is a major factor, and a
senior official has accepted that a formula approach `may well have a role to play in a final settlement based on economic reality
¶Hunter, in Competent Authorities 1986, p.594. An English court has held that the arms length rule in a treaty provision based
on Article 72 of the OECD model does not require `the substitution for every transaction between the branch and the main enterprise of the transaction that would
have been entered into if the branch and the main enterprise had been carrying on wholly separate businesses
¶ but `permits a method of ascertaining the profit to be attributed to the branch which is one which might have been agreed between the
1
Section 2.4.5 and 2.4.6, and Höppner 1983 p.222. Cf. also Saunders 1989 p.253, who states that the German criteria `basically require the German tax administration to consider that every company must
make an adequate return on capital employed or a gross profit which is compatible with that of its compe
WLWRUV¶
branch and the main enterprise if the branch had been an independent enterprise ¶
Vinelott, J. in Sun Life Assurance Co. of Canada v. Pearson 1984, p. 507. Nevertheless, the basic statutory provisions ICTA 1988 s.770 are much more
specific than the treaty wording in requiring adjustments to pricing of transactions, and might cause some difficulty for the Inland Revenue if a case were to come to
court.
However, profitsplit is considered to be appropriate only as a guide and not as a criterion in itself. The difficulty is that, if it is not based on any rigorous evaluation of
the consolidated accounts of the group of related companies, it is no more than a rough check on the profitability of the local subsidiary in relation to the group and in
comparison with other similar firms. There may frequently be good reasons for significant divergence. A TNC might limit its operations in particular markets to
highly profitable lines, or may have superior technology, which should produce much higher profits than local firms. Conversely, a foreignowned subsidiary may
experience difficulty in establishing itself in a new market, or may for other good reasons register repeated losses, in contrast with the groups more profitable
operations elsewhere.
Furthermore, the use of profit comparisons has caused disagreements among national authorities. As we have seen, it has long been accepted, at least for a branch or other
permanent establishment, that where separate accounts based on comparable market prices for specific transactions are not available, the profits could be calculated by
comparison with similar independent firms, using percentage of turnover or other appropriate coefficients. Historically, this clearly meant comparison with similar
enterprises located in the same country; but in the case of multinational banks, which frequently operate through foreign branches, Japan and the United States have taken
the view that it is more appropriate today to use global coefficients or criteria see section 1 above, and OECD 1984II paras 6470.
Finally, there is official agreement generally that the `separate enterprise ¶approach
must be kept distinct from the unitary method, which if it has any formal validity is considered at most an exceptional and subsidiary method applicable only to
permanent establishments. So long as this remains the official position, it is hard to find any formal justification for the use of `profitsplit
¶in the sense of an evaluation of the profitability of a particular affiliate in relation to that of its corporate group as a
whole. It is possible to argue that the separate enterprise criterion laid down in Article 9 of the model treaties does not require `arms length prices
¶for specific transactions, but an `arms length profit
¶for the affiliate, since it states in very general terms that where conditions between related enterprises differ from the separate enterprise
standard, the profits which would otherwise have accrued may be restored and taxed accordingly. This justified the OECD Committee in treating the question of thin
capitalization as a transfer pricing matter OECD 1987CI discussed below, s.3.c.i.
Significantly, however, the German authorities expressed a reservation to that reports reasoning, on the grounds that it was based on `the notion of an `arms length profit,
rather than on the generally accepted notion of an `arms length price µ ibid., p.36
fn.2. This demonstrates a reluctance to move away from the apparent security of specific price adjustments towards profit comparisons. The argument that the relevant
profit comparison must be with global industry averages, because local firms are not comparable, made by Japan and the US in relation to banking, may be made for other
businesses. In such cases, the `arms length profit
¶ criterion might become a very loose approximation for a global profit allocation; and this the tax administrators
certainly wish to avoid. Thus, national laws, administrative regulations, court decisions and official practice
all emphasise that profitsplit is an ancillary criterion, and the primary approach must be to discover market prices charged by independent parties dealing at arms length.
3.b Tangibles: The Search for Comparables
The US regulations, in particular, explicitly specify the Comparable Uncontrolled Price as the primary method and touchstone for pricing each category of transaction.
The search for comparables has been fiercest in relation to tangible sales, since they are the most clearly bilateral transactions; moreover, the primary alternative method,
Resale Price Minus, also depends on discovering unrelated parties in comparable circumstances: `the vital prerequisite for applying the resale price method is the
existence of substantially comparable uncontrolled resellers
¶ DuPont v. US 1979, p.450.
i The US Experience
More than twenty years of experience of administering the US regulations has shown that in a large proportion of cases where TNC pricing is examined no comparables
can be found. This has been shown quantitatively by half a dozen studies of s.482 allocation cases. The Treasurys own report of 1973 revealed that of a total of 174
adjustments to the pricing of tangibles only 36, or 20, were on the basis of CUP see Tables 4 and 5. This proportion was confirmed by academic studies based on
questionnaires sent to companies US Conference Board 1972, Burns 1980. Criticism of the Arms Length method reached a peak when the General Accounting
Office GAO published a report to the Congress in 1981, which concluded:
Because of the structure of the modern business world, IRS can seldom find an arms length price on which to base adjustments but must instead construct a price. As a
result, corporate taxpayers cannot be certain how income on intercorporate transactions that cross national borders will be adjusted and the enforcement process
is difficult and timeconsuming for both IRS and taxpayers. ... We recommend that the Secretary of the Treasury initiate a study to identify and evaluate the feasibility of
Table 4 Methods Used in s.482 Price Adjustments for Tangibles
Study Method used
CUP
Resale
Cost
Other Minus
Plus
1. Treasury 1973 20
11 27
40 2. Conf. Bd. 1972
28 13
23 36
3. Burns 1980 24
14 30
32 4. GAO 1981
15 14
26 47
5. IRS 1984 41
7 7
45 6. IRS 1987
31 18
37 14
Source: US Treasury 1988, p. 22, derived from the following: 1. US Treasury 1973 reprinted in Murray 1981 308. 2. US Conference Board report no. 555 1972. 3. Burns 1980. 4. US General Accounting Office 1981, ch. 4. 5. US IRS
1984. 6. US Treasury 1988, Appendix A, p. 8.
Table 5 Official Studies of s .482 Price Adjustments
Treas.
1973
GAO 1981
IRS 1984
No. of Corps. Or Case Files 519
823 Files with potential adjs.
871 Corps. For which adjs. made
200 Transactions for which
adjs. considered 1706
3080 Adjs. Made
886 403
2306 Adjs. Agreed
Value of adjs. In m 520
662 277
1335 4377
TANGIBLES Value in m
313 124
2632 Potential Adjs.
591 589
Adjs. Made 174
34 339
of which agreed 91
127 METHODS USED
No. No.
No. CUP
36 20
5 15
139 41
RM 19
11 4
14 24
7 CP
48 27
9 26
22 7
Other 71
40 16
47 154
45 Sources: as for Table 4, lines 1, 4 and 5. The 1973 study was based on returns for which audit was completed in 1968 and
1969; the 1981 study cases closed in 1978 and 1979; and the 1984 study those closed in 1980 and 1981.
ways to allocate income under s.482, including formula apportionment, which would lessen the present uncertainty and administrative burden created by the existing
regulations ¶US GAO 1981 p.54.
The IRS and Treasury strongly countered the conclusions of the GAO report, and the figures on which they were based. There was certainly some basis for attacking the
validity of the GAOs extraordinarily low figure of 15 for adjustments based on CUP, since the total of 34 adjustments to the pricing of tangibles was not a large
statistical sample. But what was surprising was that as few as 34 adjustments had been made to tangibles pricing, in a programme of audit including all TNCs with
assets over 250m, in which over 500 International Examiners reports were completed over a two year period. In contrast, many more adjustments were made to
the pricing of loans, services and rents 274 of the 403 adjustments; but they were almost all 240 or 87 made using safe haven rules. However, these accounted for
only 60.4m by value, compared to the 277m produced by only 34 adjustments to tangibles pricing. The clear implication is that verification of tangibles pricing, since
safe haven rules could not be used, consumed more time and expertise; but equally, it could produce more significant adjustments.
The IRS claim that pricing adjustments for tangibles were based on CUP in over 40 and perhaps as many as 50 of cases was subsequently supported by its own
comprehensive study published in 1984, based on cases closed in the two years following those covered by the GAO study. Nevertheless, even this still showed that
adjustments were more often made by `other
¶methods than by using the CUP. The most striking factor was the sharp increase in the number of adjustments made:
although the number of case files only increased from 519 to 823 1.6 times, the overall number of adjustments increased nearly sixfold, with a total value over 15
times as large; while for tangibles, adjustments increased ten times in number and over twenty times by value Table 5. Clearly, the IRS had taken to heart the
admonitions to improve enforcement of s.482, including the GAOs recommendation to use economists in all major cases not involving safe harbours Treasury 1988,
p.25. In fact, the Treasury changed tack, and the 1988 White Paper no longer attempted to defend previous practice, but proposed a new approach to pricing, the
Basic Arms Length Return Method see below.
The statistical evidence is a significant indication that there are serious difficulties in establishing arms length prices on the basis of comparables. The evaluation of
detailed qualitative factors, as well as the effect of quantity on price, make it very difficult if not impossible to establish with certainty the comparability of similar
items sold by third parties, and even of the same item sold by the same firm to third parties. Above all, few tax authorities have the time or expertise for this process.
Even the USA has had difficulty in allocating resources commensurate with the growing scale of the problem: the total number of international examiners grew from
150 in 1977 to 505 in 1988, but this was merely keeping pace with the growth of US
companies abroad, and the even more rapid expansion of foreignowned businesses in the US Woodard 1988.
ii The Administrative Burden of Scrutiny
Whether for political reasons or merely through lack of resources, other countries have put much less effort, even comparatively, into the scrutiny of transfer prices. In
the UK, the transfer pricing unit of the Board of Inland Revenue
1
was reported in 1984 to have 7 staff only one of whom was a qualified accountant. Nevertheless, this
unit was said to have been responsible for transfer price adjustments to profits `of the order of £200m
¶ in the decade 19741984; while in the single year 198788 settlements of transfer pricing cases gave an immediate tax yield of £71m, and
Controlled Foreign Company cases £12.5m.
2
In Germany the federal system means that tax assessment and collection is done by the Länder, of which only Bavaria has
inspectors with specialised training, although coordination is ensured by a Federal Finance Office with some 70 auditors of whom about 10 specialise in international
matters.
3
However, due to differences in the administration of tax enforcement, direct international comparisons of the resources and effectiveness of departments
responsible for transfer price adjustments are hard to make. Developing countries in particular have recognised that it is crucial to establish some
monitoring especially of import prices paid, not only on related company purchases, and not only for tax reasons but even more importantly to safeguard valuable foreign
exchange. The establishment of a government monitoring unit, although expensive, is likely to be highly costeffective, as was shown by countries such as Greece in the
late 1970s Ganiatsos 1981, UN 1978A; however, this type of unit is likely to be vulnerable to political pressures. especially in a period of liberalization and
encouragement of foreign investors.
1
At that time, Technical Division 2B; subsequently a single International Division has been created, including both Policy and Technical work, and the Transfer Pricing unit is now International 5B: see
UK Board of Inland Revenue 1988.
2
The figures for staffing in 1984 and yield 197484 are from a ministerial answer to a parliamentary question, Hansard 19834 vol.52 p.222; that for 198788 is given in the Management Plan of the
International Division, published in UK Board of Inland Revenue 1988 vol.3. The latter document remarks: `With regard to transfer pricing and Controlled Foreign Company casework the investigations
handled on the Section are generally into major multinationals and are complex and specialised, often taking up to 5 years to complete with an uncertain outcome. It is also possible that some Transfer
Pricing cases may finally reach the Special Commissioners over the next three years, dependent on the resources of the Solicitors Office to offer advice etc. The result is that yield fluctuates year by year,
FDQQRWEHPHDQLQJIXOO\IRUHFDVWDQGEHDUVQRUHODWLRQVKLSWRWKHVWDIILQJUHVRXUFHVSXWLQWRWKHP¶ ibid 9.9. It should be borne in mind that, some tax districts, notably those covering the City of
London, and the special Oil Taxation Office, deal directly with many cases, and have considerable expertise of their own, so that the central unit is mainly concerned with training, advice and
international liaison, and is directly concerned only with major or difficult cases.
3
Information from German Ministry of Finance, April 1987.
In the1980s, as the problems of sovereign debt and shortage of foreign exchange have come more to the fore, many states have preferred to employ private firms to provide
preshipment inspection services. This approach has been subject to political and other criticisms, but in view especially of the currency and capital flight problems of
developing countries, it has become well established. Such a system can greatly facilitate the practical task of tax authorities. The need for confidentiality need not
prevent information gathered for the purposes of one branch of government, such as customs or the Central Bank, being used by another; and although there must be some
limitations on tax authorities divulging information from tax examinations, exchange of information between government branches, subject to safeguards, is essential for
efficient administration. For example, import prices declared to Customs may differ from those returned to Tax authorities, since the incentive to inflate invoices to
reduce taxable profits or transfer funds abroad may conflict with the desire to reduce import duties.
1
3.c Safe Harbours and Intrafirm Financial Flows.
Some of the difficulties involved in establishing comparables may be avoided by the use of safe harbours. Safe harbours have two major advantages: they are easy to
administer; and if they can be internationally agreed, they can ensure that an arms length adjustment by one state will be automatically compensated by a corresponding
adjustment by the other to prevent economic double taxation. However, a safe harbour is only possible for standardised transactions taking place in competitive
markets. In such conditions, it may be possible to define a reasonably precise rule; but there is still the issue of whether such a rule should be inflexible, or merely create
a rebuttable presumption. Fairness may require that the taxpayer be allowed to demonstrate that a price charged complies with the arms length criterion even though
it is outside the safe harbour. But from the point of view of the government this `would serve only to reduce tax liability
¶ since taxpayers would normally choose to rebut the presumption if it would be advantageous US Treasury 1988, p.73,
although administrative costs must also be borne in mind. To allow both the taxpayer and the revenue to rebut the presumption would create uncertainty and defeat the
purpose of the safe harbour. Although some administrations do use a `ruleofthumb ¶
usually of an informal type, in some situations, this can hardly qualify as a safe harbour.
Loans are relatively standardised transactions taking place in highly competitive markets, and would therefore seem suitable for a safe harbour approach. For
international lending, however, this means deciding which market should provide the
1
In the UK, the Keith Committee on Revenue enforcement powers recommended increased information exchange between the Inland Revenue and other government branches, especially the
Customs and Excise, which is responsible not only for import duties but also for excise taxes including VAT.
reference point. It has proved difficult to settle this in terms of principle, largely because there is an inevitable divergence of perspective between the source country,
which is concerned to ensure that high interest rates on interaffiliate loans are not used to reduce the taxable business profits of the local subsidiary, and the parents
country of residence, which will seek a full return on loans of capital. The UN Group of Experts went furthest, in specifying that the focus should be on the creditor, and
therefore interest should be based on the creditors borrowing capacity and the interest rate either in its own country or on the relevant capital market Surrey 1978B, p.161.
This reflected the viewpoint of developing countries as capital importers; they would be reluctant to allow deduction of the higher rates of interest that would be likely to
prevail in their domestic markets, since foreign investors would benefit from lower rates in the international financial markets. The OECD report was however much
more circumspect: it merely listed the criteria to be taken into account in determining what would be a comparable loan, and in relation to the appropriate interest rate it
could only conclude that `no straightforward principle presents itself which would win general acceptance, and it would depend on the facts of the particular case
¶ OECD 1979, para.200. The US is the only major country which formally uses safe
harbour interest rates which have only since 1988 been pegged to a realistic rate, published monthly.
However, the home states of TNCs have had to accept that these firms borrow in the cheapest markets, usually offshore, to finance their foreign subsidiaries. The home
country revenue authorities have therefore shifted their attention from the rate of interest charged on interaffiliate loans to ensuring that the capital structure of foreign
subsidiaries realistically reflects the parents investment. Highly complex arrangements can be devised for financing international operations, and tax
considerations are an important element. A key factor is that interest is treated, in most cases, as an expense which is deductible from business profits. Furthermore, tax
treaties usually reduce withholding tax at source on interest to a low level, often zero. It is also possible to route such payments through a conduit company to a base
holding company in a tax haven, thus ensuring that the profits are not taxed at all see Chapter 6 above.
i Thin Capitalization
Primarily for this reason, a TNC determining the capital structure of a subsidiary is likely to favour a high ratio of debt to equity; also because interaffiliate interest
payments may be more flexible and easier to repatriate than declarations of dividend. There may also be advantages in using forms of hybrid financing, such as convertible
bonds or participating loans, which might be deductible for tax purposes while being treated as share capital from an accounting point of view. Under some circumstances
a hybrid instrument might be treated as debt in the payors country so that the service
payments are deductible interest, although they may be subject to withholding tax but as equity in the recipient state so that they are dividends and qualify for a foreign
tax credit.
However, the tax authorities may challenge such arrangements as being disguised equity contributions, or `thin capitalization
¶ This entails the rejection by the source country of the companys categorization of the nature of its investment, usually by
disallowing deductibility of some or all of the interest, and perhaps also by recategorising some of the payments as dividends and taxing them accordingly.
Although a state is free to take such action unilaterally under its own laws, it clearly raises international issues. A refusal to allow interest deductions for foreignowned
firms may be seen as an impediment to international investment. The model double tax treaties do not specifically deal with the matter, but several of the treaty
provisions offer a possible basis for a state to object to a treatypartner disallowing deduction of an interest payment, or reattributing such a payment as a dividend. Such
a disagreement would fall to be resolved under the Mutual Agreement procedures of the treaty Article 25 of the Models, see Ch. 10.3 below.
The thin capitalization issue has been addressed in general terms by the OECD Committee, which published a report favouring its treatment as a transfer pricing
question under Article 9 of the Model treaties.
1
The argument for this is that, unless a states action is justifiable under article 9, it may be contrary to article 245, which
requires nondiscrimination between local and foreignowned companies as regards deductibility of interest, royalties and other payments. However, if the thin
capitalization rules apply equally to locallyowned companies, there is no discrimination and Article 245 does not apply.
2
In fact, there is nothing in the tax treaty models requiring a state to allow the deductibility of interest. If a state goes
further than disallowing an interest deduction and reattributes a payment as a dividend, it might fall foul of Article 10, which limits source taxation of dividends to
those defined as such in Article 103:
income from shares ..., not being debtclaims, participating in profits, as well as income from other corporate rights which is subjected to the same tax treatment as
income from shares by the law of the State of which the company making the distribution is resident.
A minority of the OECD Committee considered that the exclusion of `debtclaims ¶
overrides the general inclusion of `other corporate rights ¶ and precludes reattribution
of interest as dividends; but the majority considered that in appropriate cases reattribution was permitted; and it was generally agreed that the ambiguity should be
1
OECD 1987CI, following up the brief discussion of the problem in the 1979 report, paras. 182191.
2
Nevertheless, France has explicitly reserved the right to apply its domestic law on deductibility of interest notwithstanding Article 24: OECD 1987CI para.66.
cleared up in later versions of the treaty or its commentary.
1
If thin capitalization rules are treated as transfer price adjustments permitted under Article 9, rather than a valid exercise of the source countrys unilateral jurisdiction,
then the implication is that they must comply with the Arms Length criterion. Nevertheless, some OECD member states apparently took the view that Article 9
could be read as being `illustrative
¶rather than `restrictive¶OECD 1987CI, para 49 in this context. However, the general view of the Committee has been that Article 9 is
definitive, in requiring transfer price adjustments to conform to Arms Length, and the general consensus here also was that `thin capitalization rules ought not normally to
increase the taxable profits ... to any amount greater than the arms length profit ¶
Ibid. para.49. However, Germany entered a reservation to the reports use of the concept `arms length profit
¶ rather than the more specific principle of the arms length price, and pointed out that `the consensus regarding the actual application of
the arms length principle is extremely vague and precarious ¶ibid. p.36..
Once again, however, the problem faced by the Committee has been whether to opt for a fixed rule, with the merit of certainty and predictability, or a flexible approach,
which can respond to the particular circumstances of each case. A majority took the view that a fixed capitalization ratio would be inconsistent with the Arms Length
requirement, unless it merely created a presumption which the taxpayer could rebut; and the report also urged that if a ratio is adopted, it should be fixed as high as
possible, to minimise the number of taxpayers who would be obliged to take on the burden of disproving the presumption ibid. para. 79. Clearly, this type of safe
harbour would have the disadvantages for the revenue identified by the US Treasury and mentioned above.
On the other hand, the Committee recognised the wide discretionary scope of the casebycase approach. Although much comparative information is available to tax
authorities about company financing, a company can normally choose its capital structure from a wide range of options depending on the specific conditions.
Furthermore, it may not be appropriate to ask what level of debt an independent third party, such as a bank, would have allowed a company, since such a party would not
have available to it the amount of information which a parent would have about its own subsidiary ibid. para. 76. Thus, the Committee could come to no better
conclusion than that the judgments of tax authorities and courts should be consistent and based on evidence of transactions between independent persons, applied in a
reasonable manner para. 78. In practice however, it seems that revenue authorities do operate defined ratios as an informal guide, to avoid the uncertainty of a caseby
1
OECD 1987CI. paras.5660. The protocol to the FranceUS treaty signed in 1988 included a provision widening the definition of dividends to include any income treated as income from shares by
the country of residence of the distributing company.
case approach, as well as the timeconsuming process of individual evaluations.
1
However, the validity of Revenue challenges to relatedcompany thin capitalization based on analogies to thirdparty `arms length
¶situation has been directly challenged by the increased use by many companies of leveraged recapitalizations, which have
made it very hard to define a `normal ¶capital structure Briffett 1990.
Thus, the weapons available to revenue authorities are at best cumbersome, in relation to the complexity of financing devices open to companies produced by the
fertile minds of the highlypaid accountancy and law firms. For example, the power to adjust related company financial transactions may be circumvented by channelling
the loan through an unrelated company, backtoback with a loan to it from a non resident affiliate. Further advantages can be gained by using dualresident companies,
whose accounts can be consolidated with those of related firms in two jurisdictions, thus allowing a `double dip
¶ or deduction of the same interest twice.
2
These are merely some of the simpler schemes devised by the international tax specialists. The
complexity of financing arrangements makes it very difficult for the authorities to operate effectively with precise rules; but it is equally hard to apply broad anti
avoidance provisions without accusations of arbitrariness.
Once a particular form of financing has become established, a move against it by one state results in objections from the business lobbies that they are being unfairly
treated and their competitiveness would suffer. Thus, the growth of debtfinanced company acquisitions LBOs leveraged buyouts, many of them from abroad, led
the US Congress to enact provisions in 1989 to limit deductibility of interest paid to related parties. These rules against `earnings stripping
¶provide for nondeductibility of `excess interest
¶paid to a related person if the recipient does not pay US tax on such income, and the payor corporation has a debt ratio over 1.5 to 1 and `excess
interest expense ¶ interest payments above a certain proportion of income Mentz,
Carlisle Nevas 1990. Business lobbies on behalf of overseas investors objected that this denial of interest deduction entailed a unilateral override of tax treaties see
Chapter 11 below. On the other hand, the US measures at least have the merit of providing a specific statutory rule.
A comprehensive solution would require an internationally coordinated approach. This could take the form of international agreement on more precise thin
capitalization rules, although the increased complexity of company financing would make such rules arbitrary in operation, and probably discriminatory as between
domestic and international transactions. A more radical approach would entail a joint move to end the deductibility of interest altogether, which might be coupled with an
appropriate reduction in marginal corporate tax rates Bird 1988. While this has been
1
Thus, the UK Inland Revenue has been widely stated to operate an informal safe harbour debtequity ratio of onetoone, as well as a rule of thumb that pretax profits should be at least three times the
interest expense: see Tomsett 1989 p.143.
2
This is being combated by provisions against dual residence.
considered by individual countries for example, by the US Treasury in the course of the Reagan tax reforms a concerted decision would be difficult to achieve.
ii Global Trading and Transfer Parking
Special difficulties have increasingly arisen in dealing with the allocation of gains and losses of firms which are transnational financial intermediaries investment
houses, both banks and stockbrokers operating in the key financial markets around the world. In principle, their activities can be dealt with according to the traditional
separate enterprise approach, by attributing the profit from each transaction to the branch or subsidiary making the sale, unless it is considered to be a dependent agent
for the parent or head office and therefore entitled only to a commission similar to the `merchanting profit
¶of a wholesaler. However, the growing complexity of multiple operations in different global markets, exploiting the possibilities of arbitrage and of
market scope by trading assets continuously on an almost 24hour per day basis, have undermined the effectiveness of the separate enterprise approach. Global trading
offers considerable advantages of hedging and arbitrage exploiting even small price differences in different markets as well as access to a wider client base. An
important element is regulatory arbitrage: exploiting differences in the regulatory treatment of transactions between markets. This includes not only or primarily tax
treatment, but also various monetary and banking controls and prudential requirements, such as capital adequacy and liquidity rules, prohibitions of maturity
mismatching and limits on foreign exchange exposure.
A direct means of regulatory arbitrage is for global finance houses to exploit the possibilities of internal intrafirm trading by the `transfer parking
¶ of transactions such as loans and foreign exchange positions. The use of transfer parking became
publicised by investigations into the activities of New Yorks Citibank, following allegations made by an employee in 1977, which were revealed in a court case for
unfair dismissal, and were followed up by investigations by the SEC and a US Congressional Subcommittee.
1
Parking entails transferring a loan or foreign exchange position to a related branch or subsidiary, either by booking it directly to the related
entity, or by undertaking an offsetting transaction, sometimes returning it also by a `roundtrip
¶or `backtoback¶procedure. In the highly competitive money markets, a margin of a fraction of one percent
determines profit or loss, and structuring transactions to minimise the costs of regulatory compliance may become a necessity. Thus, Citibank in Paris registered a
foreign exchange loss by instructing New York to direct the Nassau `branch ¶merely
a separate set of books in New York to buy 6m at FFr 4.7275, and then to resell the
1
The material is usefully summarised by Sarah Bartlett 1981, and in Richard Dale 1984, Appendix 2, `Citibanks `Rinky
LQNHDOV
DVH6WXG\LQ5HJXODWRU\UELWUDJH¶
dollars to the New York and Brussels branches, for resale back to Paris, at FFr 4.7375. This reduced the taxable profits in Paris, and although the Nassau branch
profits were taxable in the US, the banks excess foreign tax credits still made it worthwhile. In such cases, where there is evidence that the sale and repurchase were
simultaneous, it might be possible to establish tax evasion. In the absence of such proof, the validity of this type of transaction could depend on whether the sales were
within prevailing market ranges, and whether they were booked in a lowtax centre in anticipation of profit, or retrospectively once it was known that a profit and not a loss
had been achieved Bartlett 1981.
Citibanks transactions were also part of more complex arrangements whereby the Paris office could avoid French tax on foreign exchange profits, converting them into
lowertaxed interest income, by swapping a deposit in a low interest currency for a high interest currency which was placed with a related branch, giving Paris a loss on
foreign exchange from the forward discount on the high interest currency, but interest earnings from the interest rate spread between the two currencies Dale
1984, p.201. The potential tax advantages of linking interest rate and currency swaps have been summarised as follows: `Of course, with careful construction ... there are
opportunities for linking swaps to high interest borrowings of a soft currency with resulting benefits, such as the creation of taxfree gains and a capital gains tax loss,
all in a fully hedged situation
¶Selter, Godfrey Atkinson 1990. Tax authorities are not powerless against such manoeuvres: they can reattribute a
profit transferred by the rebooking of a transaction; or more radically, can re attribute all the profits made by an offshore office, on the grounds that it is effectively
managed from the local branch. This step was indeed taken by the German authorities in relation to business booked to the Nassau unit of Citibank based in Frankfurt Dale
1984, p.199. However, they face major enforcement problems due to the sheer number of deals and the dispersed nature of financial markets. These markets are
dominated by a network of major participants, so that the rates quoted in the multiplicity of bilateral deals result in a prevailing price range; but there is no single
market and no universally recognised market rate.
1
As Edwards, the dismissed Citibank employee pointed out: `In order to get a full picture of a Citibank interbank
transactions, it is necessary to examine its individual components at all branches involved. The chances of random sampling in several Citibank branches producing a
single complete parking transaction are almost nonexistent ¶cited in Bartlett 1981,
p.110. Neither bank regulators nor tax authorities have the resources for continuous monitoring of such transactions on a worldwide scale. Ominously, Dale concludes
that such activities `far from being confined to Citibank, are endemic to multinational banking
¶Dale 1984, p.204.
1
Report of Citibanks Audit Committee, prepared by the law firm Shearman and Sterling and accountants Peat, Marwick and Mitchell, cited in Bartlett 1981, p.111.
Not surprisingly, it has been difficult for the national authorities to develop their own approaches to taxation of the profits from global financial trading, let alone establish
agreed principles. The OECD Committee published one short study on taxation of foreign exchange gains and losses, which dealt only with gains or losses made
incidentally in the course of a business which is not normally that of dealing in currencies, and even that report was described as a preliminary step in a rapidly
developing field OECD 1988, para.5. On the treatment of currency swaps, the report was confined to a bare description para. 70, not mentioning intrafirm swaps,
and stating that `The tax treatment of payments under instruments of these types is, in general, still being developed, and it is not yet, therefore, possible to comment on it
very informatively
¶ibid. para 71. In the meantime, the possibility of wide divergences in tax treatment created
significant uncertainty. In response to a request from the US IRS studies were published by specialists, both in private practice and in the government service
Plambeck 1990; Ernst Young 1991, which disagreed as to the appropriateness of formula apportionment. However, whether an apportionment or a separate entity
approach is adopted, it would require detailed agreement between the major taxing authorities on the characterization of transactions and the attribution of gains and
losses between the elements of a global trading team based in different offices. The official position of national tax authorities, and the view expressed by a consultants
report for the Institute of International Bankers, was suspicious of `arbitrary
¶ allocation by formula, and preferred profitattribution by identification of the
functions carried out and risks assumed by each party Ernst Young 1991; but the formula approach was argued to make more economic sense, by acknowledging that
the profits of a globallytraded book of assets result from the synergy of the team as a whole Plambeck 1990. A formula approach would require prior agreement between
the various parties, which critics argued would be hard to achieve, but was put forward in its favour as being administratively simpler; while administration of a
pricing system based on the separate entity approach would be facilitated by an advanced ruling agreement.
iii Proportionate Allocation of Financing Costs
Transfer parking is primarily a problem in relation to banks and other financial enterprises. However, many manufacturing TNCs are also major financial institutions
in their own right. They are also of necessity active in foreign exchange markets, and the definition and allocation of their tax base will be significantly affected by the
approach under national tax rules to currency conversion and foreign exchange gains and losses OECD 1988. This is therefore another area where a concerted and
coordinated approach by the major tax authorities is urgently required, to remove the inducement to firms to reduce their costs by international tax avoidance and arbitrage.
A different approach to intrafirm finance would be to allow or require deduction based on the average cost of external borrowing for the firm as a whole. This position
has been taken in the US rules which require allocation of interest expense of a single corporation between its domestic and foreign activities according to the ratio of
domestic to foreign assets Internal Revenue Code s.864. This applies especially to banking, since transnational banks do much of their foreign business through
branches. Moreover, the Tax Reform Act 1986 extended this to consolidated corporate groups, including multinational groups falling within a defined affiliation
rule. This rule was fixed by the IRS in temporary regulations at 80 ownership. It was soon after revealed that the Ford Motor group had decided to reorganise its
financial, insurance and leasing subsidiaries to be owned through a new holding company, 25 of the shares of which would be placed with institutional investors, so
that the Ford ownership would fall below the 80 threshold.
1
However, the apportionment of interest expense has been criticised and rejected by a majority of the OECD Committee, which took the view that both a foreign branch
and a subsidiary should be permitted to deduct the interest actually charged on inter affiliate or parent company loans, provided the rate is arms length OECD 1984II,
especially paras 5862. Both Japan and the US took the view, opposed by the majority of OECD members, that Article 7 of the model treaty permits but does not
require deductibility of the interest charged between bank branches and the head office. Japan only allows deduction of the actual interbranch interest charged if the
source of the funds can be traced and documented; but since this is not normally possible, the interest cost allowed is normally a reasonable estimate based on
prevailing rates. The US approach takes the view that money is fungible or at least money of the same currency. Foreign bank branches in the US are permitted to
deduct interest based on the original source of funds only if that original price is the price of Eurodollar borrowing; otherwise, a `currency pools
¶method is used, which takes the average cost of borrowing for the corporation as a whole in that currency.
This is defended as fairer and simpler, since `a banks receipts and payments of interest may be regarded as all flowing into and out of one common pool
¶ ibid. para.59. However, the Committee took the view that it was not simpler to operate,
since the detailed calculation of the cost of borrowings would be complex. More importantly, it disregards the specific role of the particular branch, which might not
be typical of the bank as a whole, and might result in different costs, and thus in higher or lower earnings.
The broader problem is the anomaly entailed in apportioning or attributing costs on the basis of an average of the whole enterprise, while still purporting to tax the branch
on a separate enterprise basis. In that respect, the question of the cost of money to a
1
Tax Notes 30 October 1989, p.531.
banking firm is part of the larger problem of allocation of joint costs.
3.d Central Services: Joint Costs and Mutual Benefits
A matter which has long been the subject of conflicting views between the home and host countries of TNCs is the allocation of charges in respect of central management
and service costs. Indeed, the model treaties still include a provision, inherited from the League drafts, specifying that allowance must be made in the calculation of the
business profits of a permanent establishment for `executive and general administrative expenses
¶ incurred on its behalf Article 73. However, the UN model explicitly limits the deduction to `actual expenses
¶in respect of management or other services or the use of patent or other rights; in contrast, the USA prefers to
include in its treaties a specific reference to the deductibility in calculating branch profits of a `reasonable allocation
¶ of research and development as well as other expenses incurred for the purposes of the enterprise as a whole.
For separately incorporated subsidiaries, there is no explicit international provision for dealing with such central service costs, but the starting point is the `separate
enterprise ¶standard of Article 9. Nevertheless, it has been accepted that some of the
general overhead costs of a multinational company group are incurred on behalf of the group as a whole, in respect of services provided to its members. The group may
be structured so that such central services are provided either by the parent company, or by a regional centre for affiliates in that region, or by specific service centres such
as distribution and marketing centres, a captive insurance company, or research laboratories. Such services may be administrative, for example planning and
coordination, budgetary control, accounting and legal services, and computing; they may relate to staff matters such as recruitment and training; or they may relate to
production in a broad sense, covering joint purchasing, distribution and marketing services including advertising, and research and development, including the
administration and protection of intellectual property rights.
From the point of view of TNCs, these represent costs which must be deductible somewhere against gross profits, and they consider that tax authorities should not
interfere with any reasonable arrangement for sharing or allocating them. The tax authorities for their part fear that a TNC may allocate such costs `in order to obtain a
tax advantage or to neutralise a tax disadvantage
¶OECD 1984III para.7; and they are unwilling to accept unreservedly the principle that all such expenses must be
deductible somewhere.
1
In principle, therefore, the attribution of such costs must be justified in terms of the
1
For example, costs connected with exempt income may not be deductible OECD 1984III para.18.
arms length criterion. This raises two separate but interrelated questions: whether a charge can be justified, and what it should be. In principle, a charge can be justified
only if the recipient can be shown to have derived a benefit. This `benefit test ¶is most
easily satisfied if the charge is made directly for specific service transactions, on a feeforservice basis. Preferably, such a fee should be verifiable as arms length by
comparison with the cost of similar services from unrelated suppliers: for example, legal services could be billed at an hourly rate, which could be compared with the rate
for comparable services from independent law firms.
1
In practice, however, direct feeforservice charging is frequently difficult. The main reason is that central services often do not benefit one affiliate exclusively. This is
obviously the case for services carried out for the joint benefit of all or several affiliates, for example an international advertising campaign. Indeed, it could be
argued that even if on one occasion a specific service is carried out for a particular recipient, there may well be a subsequent benefit to others if knowledge or expertise
is thereby acquired. Furthermore, the benefit may be indirect andor nonspecific: it is common, for example, to pay a retainer to ensure the availability of some types of
professional or specialised services, which may in the event not be required. Thus, it may be very difficult or impossible to evaluate the proportion of the benefit
attributable to a particular affiliate; or to do so might require disproportionate administrative costs.
It is therefore common for central service costs to be charged by an `indirect ¶method
apportioning the costs. Most tax authorities have been obliged to accept this, although some only do so if direct charging is impossible, and an actual benefit can be shown.
On the other hand, the US rules mandate US parent companies to make a cost apportionment to foreign affiliates for joint costs wherever there is a mutual benefit,
based on the relative benefits. Apportionment of costs may be done by i cost sharing, based on the estimated share in the benefits of each affiliate; in the case of
productionrelated services, this may be done by a markup on the price of goods sold; or ii `costfunding
¶ by contributions from each affiliate based for example on gross turnover sometimes known as the `fixedkey
¶method. The difficulty is that these methods essentially entail allocation of costs by formula,
which runs counter to the arms length approach. Nevertheless, following the 1979 OECD report the business lobby groups pressed for acceptance of cost contribution
arrangements. In its more detailed report of 1984, the OECD Committee went some way towards accepting the arguments of TNCs for these indirect methods, although
several countries still had significant reservations, particularly to costfunding, where the charges may be unrelated to the benefit received. This report accepted that even
1
This is likely to mean the comparable rate in the country of the recipient rather than of the provider, since deductibility is decided by the source country.
though costsharing does not correspond to arrangements applied between unrelated parties, it may nevertheless be justified by the `special situation of MNEs
¶OECD 1984III, para.63. It laid down principles, described as nonexhaustive, which would
facilitate the acceptance of a costsharing arrangement: it should be established in advance by a clearly formulated and binding contract, covering all affiliates which
might be expected to benefit, observed consistently over several years and modified as soon as there is any relevant alteration in the activities of group members; the costs
should be established by accepted accounting principles, and should entitle contributors to receive those services without any other payment OECD 1984III,
para 67.
This goes some way towards accepting the proportionate allocation of joint costs within an international company group. However, many countries, especially those
which have been mainly recipients of direct investment, are still very restrictive in their allowance of deduction for joint costs. The German rules permit costsharing
contracts, but they are quite strict in requiring proof of actual services performed, although where the volume fluctuates over several years an average charge may be
appropriate Rule 6.2.3. They also exclude a large category of costs coming within the `shareholder costs
¶of the parent company. This concept has proved controversial. The OECD Committee distinguished between a loose and decentralised firm where
the role of the parent may be that of monitoring its investments, and an integrated and more centralised TNC. In the latter case, the managerial and coordination activities of
the parent could be regarded as generating `extra profits ¶which accrue primarily to
the subsidiaries and only indirectly to the parent, and therefore should be shared as a joint cost. Some OECD members however rejected this, and the issue was left to be
dealt with bilaterally OECD 1984III, paras 3343.
Finally, there is the question of whether a service charge can include a profit element. The OECD Committee concluded that a profit markup is always appropriate in some
cases, particularly where the provider is specially established to perform such services, or is particularly capable of them and they are especially beneficial to the
recipient. When a direct feeforservice is charged based on market prices, the charge will presumably include a profit element, unless the provider is operating below
capacity. However, when the charge is indirect and based on costsharing, it is argued that since there is no risk, a profit element is inappropriate. This is the position taken
in the German rules, but they permit an allowance for the cost of capital invested.
3.e Intangibles and Synergy Profits
The category of intangibles covers a very broad range of assets, related both to production and to marketing, and generally originating from knowledge, information
or skills. They may be legally recognised as forms of property, such as patents, copyrights, designs, and trademarks; or they may be other types of legally protected
rights, such as confidential data and business knowhow, which are independent of the services of a particular individual and therefore belong to the enterprise.
1
Intangibles are especially important to TNCs, whose preeminence is often due to technological advances, product differentiation, market positioning or distinctive
managerial methods.
The transfer of rights to intangibles has two aspects: a payment for their value, and the acquisition of an asset which can generate an income stream. Therefore, such
transfers are especially sensitive, since they can have a major effect on the distribution of the profits of a TNC. As with interest and central service charges, the
source country will be concerned to ensure that royalties or fees payable for intangibles do not excessively reduce taxable business profits. Some countries,
notably in Latin America, do not allow deductibility of royalties paid abroad, but this is only possible if the recipient is not a national of a treaty state, since the model
treaties require nondiscrimination. However, all countries frequently monitor carefully the extent and level of payments made for use of intellectual property rights,
especially if made to lowtax countries: for example, Germany collects data on such payments especially to Switzerland and Liechtenstein, and maintains files for
comparative purposes Germany, Bundestag 1986, 1415. At the same time, the home country of a TNC will wish to ensure an adequate contribution or return from
its foreign affiliates for the use of such assets. In addition, an intangible may be transferred to a subsidiary located in a country with a convenient tax regime: indeed,
many countries offer specific incentives to try to attract hightechnology investments. This can be hard for the home country of a TNC to counter through antibase
company or CFC measures: since the basecountry affiliate will be carrying out a genuine manufacturing or service activity, it is hard to classify its profits as `passive
income
¶ see Chapter 7 section 2 above.
2
Therefore, the question will often be whether the price paid for the intangible fairly reflects its value in relation to the
profits it helps to generate. Although an intangible is often a specific identifiable property right, its particular
nature as intellectual, scientific or artistic property gives it peculiar cost and profit characteristics. The essential problem is uncertainty and risk. It is necessary to make
large upfront investments for basic scientific research and other creative activity such as design, or of even larger sums for applying these ideas to production or
marketing, while no definite, measurable gains can be anticipated. Thus,
At each stage in the R D process, the final commercial benefits to be derived remain uncertain ... and the degree of risk involved makes it difficult to estimate
benefits from the outlays made which, in the event that some R D projects prove successful commercially, will only materialise in the future. Moreover, MNEs will
1
See the definition in the US tax code s.936h3b.
2
Indeed, a special problem has been posed for the US by US corporations transferring intangibles to subsidiaries in Puerto Rico, to take advantage of tax incentives enacted by the US itself for possessions
corporations.
understandably seek to recoup the cost of financing unsuccessful research from the results of successful research. OECD 1979 para.80.
These characteristics create significant difficulties in establishing an arms length price for an intangible. First, it can be especially difficult to establish an arms length
price based on a comparable, since the value of intangibles frequently lies in their difference or even uniqueness. Nevertheless, some authorities accept that the best that
can be done is to evaluate the appropriateness of the terms of a transfer of intangibles in a general way, by comparison with similar transactions in the same industry, and
perhaps using as a check the profit produced for the transferee over a period of time. Thus, the Italian Ministry of Finance in 1980 provided, for certainty and speed of
administration, `safe harbour
¶ guidelines for patent royalties, of up to 2 of sales provided there is a prior written contract, and evidence of actual benefit; over 2
and up to 5 could be acceptable for special factors originality, obsolescence, exclusivity etc; and over 5 of sales only in exceptional circumstances such as the
high technological level of the industry Italy, Ministry of Finance 1980. This type of approach offers an easily administrable rule, but may prove inflexible.
Where an adequate comparable cannot be found, it is difficult to fix an arms length price based on cost, since `the actual open market price of intangible property is not
related in a consistent manner to the costs involved in developing it ¶OECD 1979
para. 100. The OECD report therefore concluded that cost can at best provide some guidance as to the lower limit of a price.
Alternatively, some TNCs have used costcontribution arrangements, under which affiliates pay a share of the direct and indirect costs of a research programme based
on the proportionate benefit they are expected to derive, in exchange for rights in the intangibles that are produced. These arrangements are similar to the costsharing or
costfunding methods used for central services discussed above; and they raise, even more acutely, the same questions: is there a clear benefit for the recipient, and does
the method used to fix the contribution fairly reflect the expected benefit. The 1979 OECD report pointed out that `such arrangements might open up opportunities for
profit transfers disguised as deductions for costs
¶ and stressed the `need for a strict interpretation of the notion of real benefit
¶ to ensure that participants only pay for expenditure which is really in their interests OECD 1979 para.115.
The German rules allow costcontribution contracts for research, on the same conditions as for central administrative services: they should be based on a clear prior
contract, distributing actual identifiable direct and indirect costs by a recognised accounting method, in exchange for rights to the intangibles produced without any
supplementary payments, and making an apportionment of costs based on the benefits anticipated Section 7 of the 1983 rules. The US regulations of 1968 also allowed
costsharing agreements, provided they are in writing, and reflect a good faith effort
by participants to bear their proportion of costs and risks on an arms length basis regulation 14822d4.
1
The 1988 White Paper conceded that costsharing could still be acceptable after the enactment of the `commensurate with income
¶ requirement by Congress see below, but only under strict conditions. In particular,
the sharing of costs should not be confined to single products which might enable a foreign subsidiary to benefit from a highprofit item without paying for lowerprofit
or unsuccessful research, but should normally be based on product areas defined at least by 3digit SIC Standard Industrial Classification code; although either tax
payer or IRS could show that a narrower or broader agreement is more appropriate US Treasury 1988 chs. 12 and 13.
Thus, the problems involved in establishing arms length prices for specific intrafirm transactions are at their most intractable when it comes to intangibles. Intangibles are
likely to be distinct if not unique, throwing into doubt the validity of comparisons with similar items, if any are available on the market. Pricing based on costs is
extremely difficult, since they are essentially joint cost factors with uncertain outcomes, so that either fixing a price based on cost, or allocating cost contributions
in relation to anticipated benefit, is likely to be arbitrary.
Above all, intangibles most clearly raise the problem of the allocation of profits from synergy: the additional profits generated for an integrated firm by reason of its
features as an organization, and not attributable specifically to any of its parts. Like joint costs, synergy profits cut to the heart of the separate enterprise approach to the
taxation of international company groups, since such profits by definition cannot be attributed to one particular affiliate. Both problems also entail the politicization of the
transfer pricing question, since the issue posed is the allocation of profit rather than its attribution. If a country accepts deductibility of payments from a local operating
subsidiary of a TNC for intangibles owned or developed elsewhere, it will be allowing a deduction from gross profits, or essentially a tax subsidy, for research
based abroad. Furthermore, countries compete in offering tax advantages for high technology operations, and a TNC may transfer rights to intangibles to a subsidiary
located in a country with an advantageous tax regime, so that the TNC benefits from lower taxation of the additional monopoly profit. Thus for example, the German
authorities have been particularly vigilant in scrutinising technology royalties and licence fees paid to foreign related companies, especially to those located in
Switzerland and Liechtenstein German Bundestag 1986, p.14.
1
These criteria were expressed in much more general terms than the draft regulations proposed in 1966, which had put forward detailed rules: 31 Fed.Reg. 10394.
3.f The Commensurate with Income Standard and the US White Paper
The experience of these difficulties led to proposals by the US authorities in 1988 for a new approach. As has already been mentioned, there is a long history of political
concern about the effectiveness of US taxation of USbased TNCs. Specifically, when Congress attacked tax deferral with the Subpart F provisions in 1962, it
considered proposals to require formula apportionment if a TNC could not prove comparable arms length transfer prices; these were withdrawn following
administration assurances that the desired result could be obtained by increased enforcement of s.482. Nevertheless, there has been continuing debate about the
effectiveness of enforcement of the section and of the 1968 regulations, which reached a peak with the GAO report of 1981. Although the IRS responded vigorously
to those criticisms, both the IRS and the Treasury were aware of underlying problems with the arms length method.
These concerns resulted in a provision in the mammoth Tax Reform Act of 1986 amending s.482, the first substantial amendment of that section since 1928. This
provision, popularly referred to as the `superroyalty ¶ added the following final
sentence to the section:
In the case of any transfer or license of intangible property within the meaning of s.936h3B, the income with respect to such transfer or license shall be
commensurate with the income attributable to the intangible.
At the same time, Congress referred to continuing unresolved difficulties with s.482, and asked for a comprehensive study of intercompany pricing rules giving careful
consideration to whether the existing regulations should be amended. The result was a bulky discussion document issued by the Treasury and IRS in October 1988, `A
Study of Intercompany Pricing
¶ This study identified two major problems in the enforcement of s.482. First was the
difficulty of obtaining adequate information to evaluate pricing, leading to long delays in closing cases. It argued that the burden was on taxpayers to document
established pricing policies, but evidence from IRS examiners showed that most firms sought to justify the prices charged only when challenged, and by reference to
whatever method most closely approximated to those prices.
1
The main problem, to which the bulk of the study was addressed, was the pricing of intangibles. Although
this, and especially the problem of `high profit intangibles ¶ was the explicit focus,
1
The study urged a more aggressive use of administrative summons procedures by examiners see Chapter 10.2.a below. It also pointed to the need for special scrutiny of the growing volume of direct
investment into the US, in view of evidence of substantially lower profit levels being reported for foreignowned TNCs US Treasury 1988 p.15. Although this point was given less attention initially
than the remaining major parts of the report, the issue of the apparently low tax liability of foreign investors in the US later came to the fore, as mentioned in section 2.b above.
the study had farreaching implications, since the pricing of intangibles relates closely to charging for central services generally, and is also often `bundled
¶in the price of tangibles. Hence, the question of intangibles is central to the structure of intrafirm
relationships. The White Paper articulated the implications of the `commensurate with income
¶ requirement inserted by Congress into s.482, while arguing that it is compatible with
the arms length standard. To do so, it put forward a new pricing method, based on rate of return, called the Basic Arms Length Return Method quickly labelled
BALRM or the `ballroom ¶ method, and severely circumscribed the application of
other methods.
i Restriction of the CUP Method
As to comparables, the study argued that the CUP method can only be relied upon if an `exact comparable
¶ can be found. An exact comparable would be a transaction transferring the same intangible to an unrelated party. Since such transfers are usually
exclusive, it need not be in respect of the same market. However, there must be substantial comparability both of external factors overall size of the market, degree
of competition, collateral or continuing relationships, and of internal factors the terms of the contract. An `inexact comparable
¶ involving a similar intangible, may be useful to provide comparative information, but cannot be the sole basis to
determine pricing. It can only be relied upon if `the differences between it and the related party transaction can be reflected by a reasonable number of adjustments that
have definite and ascertainable effects on the terms of the arrangement ¶US Treasury
1988, p.91. The study was especially critical of reliance on industry standards or averages.
This would severely restrict the use of the CUP method. The White Paper stated that comparability would be easy to demonstrate in cases of widely available technology
such as pocket calculators, digital watches or microwave ovens. But such technology is unlikely to be transferred within an integrated TNC unless it has distinct properties:
for example, ballpoint pen technology is widely available, but a company such as Parker Pen still commands premium prices based on unique intangibles. Thus, in a
case following the White Paper but decided under the pre1986 law, the Tax Court took the view that nonexclusive licences to soft contact lens manufacturing
technology, granted by Bausch Lomb to its production subsidiary in Ireland, could be evaluated on the basis of comparables, and rejected the IRS view that the unrelated
party prices were not fully comparable because of the lower volumes involved Bausch Lomb v. Commr. 1989.
1
These examples also demonstrate that the `exact comparability ¶requirement applies
to sales of tangibles which embody an intangible. If components, ingredients or subassemblies embody design or production technology, or marketing intangibles
1
This decision was upheld by the 2nd Circuit Court of Appeals on 14 May 1991.
such as brand identification, the requirement that a comparable be `exact ¶will reduce
the application of the CUP method for tangibles also.
ii Periodic Adjustments
The commensurate with income requirement also entails that the return for a transfer of an intangible must normally be subject to periodic adjustment, to reflect the actual
profit earned from it. The study defends this as compatible with arms length, citing evidence that unrelated parties also renegotiate terms, either on the basis of explicit
clauses providing for renegotiation or by using termination clauses to do so.
1
Hence, payments fixed by reference to either exact or inexact comparables must be reviewed,
and adjusted if there has been a significant unforeseen change in profitability due to subsequent events. However, periodic adjustment can be avoided if the taxpayer can
point to an exactly comparable arrangement which does not permit adjustment US Treasury 1988, p.64.
iii The Arms Length Return Method
The study put great reliance on the proposed new `arms length return ¶method, which
should be used if there is no exact comparable and to adjust a price based on an inexact comparable. This identifies the assets and factors of production employed by
each related party, and allocates to them a `market ¶rate of return. The first step is a
functional analysis, breaking down the activities carried out by the parties into their component functions; next, those functions with measurable assets or production
factors can be assigned a market rate of return on the value of those assets. The residual profit is then normally assigned to the parent company, since it is considered
to be attributable to the nonmeasurable intangible assets. The reasoning is that many of the functions carried out by affiliated companies are also carried out by unrelated
firms, and information will be available about their normal rates of return on measurable factors plant, labour, equipment, working capital and routine know
how. In that sense, this is an arms length method, since it is attributing profits based on those of comparable firms in the industry. It therefore resembles the profit
comparison approaches based on `empirical
¶ methods or the use of `coefficients¶ long permitted in international practice for permanent establishments, and also
practised by several countries in relation to subsidiaries, as a fallback if evidence based on market transactions is not available as discussed earlier in this chapter.
1
SSHQGL[RIWKH:KLWH3DSHUSURYLGHVDCYHU\SUHOLPLQDU\¶DQDO\VLVRIXQUHODWHGSDUW\OLFHQFH agreements obtained from the files of the Securities and Exchange Commission, and a literature
review, to show that licensors seek to secure a riskfree return commensurate with actual profitability. But the study concedes that the Congressional enactment of the commensurate with income
requirement was a legislative rejection of the tax court decision in French v. Commr. 1973, which held that a longterm fixedrate royalty agreement could not be adjusted under s.482 to take into
account subsequent unforeseen events.
The major difficulty with the BALRM, however, is the way it separates `measurable ¶
factors, to which a normal rate of return is assigned, and then assumes that the residual profit is attributable to the parent company. This was immediately criticised
by some tax specialists as an attempt by the IRS to treat foreign subsidiaries as `contract manufacturers
¶ despite tax court decisions rejecting such a result Fuller 1988. It certainly seems that the rate of return method proposed in the white paper
has grown out of the analyses by IRS economists of company accounts in s.482 cases, using a `profit split
¶first to support a price adjustment and finally, in the Eli Lilly case, as the basis for the adjustment.
In Eli Lilly, the Circuit Court upheld the Tax Courts `profit split ¶ methodology,
which `divides combined revenues based on an ad hoc assessment of the contributions of the assets and activities of the commonly controlled enterprises
¶Eli Lilly v. Commr. 1988, p.871. However, in that case, on the view taken by the courts
both the related parties owned some intangibles. Lilly had set up a manufacturing subsidiary in Puerto Rico, to which it had transferred valuable drug patents in
exchange for stock, while retaining the US marketing intangibles trade names etc.. The IRS challenged the transfer, on the ground that if the parties had been unrelated
the transferor would have required payments for the continuing research and development programme; this would have meant treating the Puerto Rico subsidiary
as a contract manufacturer. The courts, however, accepted that the stock transfer was valuable consideration, and judged that Eli Lillys high profits from the US sales of
the drug, based on its US marketing intangibles, provided sufficient funding of the research effort. But the Tax Court first reevaluated the costs attributable to each
party and allocated an appropriate rate of return on those costs including a return to the US parent of 100 on marketing costs; and then adjusted the profit split on the
residual profit to a ratio of 4555 Lilly had allowed 4060, reflecting its view of the relative contributions of Lilly USs marketing intangibles and Lilly PRs production
intangibles.
1
Hence, although the US courts have not yet accepted a profit split which treats a foreign subsidiary as a mere contract manufacturer, this is because they have accepted
that the subsidiary validly owned some intangibles see also Searle v. Commr. 1987. The White Paper argued that the profit splits accepted by the courts in previous cases
were arbitrary or had `no discernible rationale
¶ and this was the reason for developing a `careful functional analysis
¶US Treasury 1988, p.39, i.e. the BALRM
1
The Circuit Court upheld all the Tax Courts adjustments except a charge to Lilly P.R. for research and development expenses, which it considered incompatible with the acceptance of the patentsfor
stock transfer: ibid. p.871. In response to the Lilly case s.936h was added to the Tax Code in 1982, so that possessions corporations must split the revenue from intangibles at least 5050 with their US
parent. The 1986 Tax Reform Act, in adding the commensurate with income requirement to s.482, also amended s.367d2 so that recognition of a transfer of intangibles is conditional on payments
CFRPPHQVXUDWHZLWKWKHLQFRPHDWWULEXWDEOHWRWKHLQWDQJLEOH¶
method. The difficulty is that functional analysis is only precise in relation to `measurable
¶factors. If there are synergy profits, functional analysis cannot provide a precise allocation.
This the White Paper accepts, in its discussion of what it calls the `profit split addition to the basic arms length return method
¶ It countenances that, where a large TNC has foreign subsidiaries that perform complex functions, take significant risks
and own significant assets, it would be appropriate to divide the `residual ¶or synergy
profits according to the relative value of the intangibles contributed or risks assumed by the parties. It is conceded that `it is easier to state this principle than to describe in
detail how it is to be applied in practice ¶ and that `splitting the intangible income in
such cases will be largely a matter of judgment ¶US Treasury 1988, p.101. This is
perhaps a concession to the USs main treaty partners, some of which may be reluctant to accept an approach which allocates the entirety of the synergy profits of
US TNCs to the parent company.
1
Thus, the full rigour of the BALRM may be confined to subsidiaries with highprofit intangibles in convenient lowtax locations, such as Ireland or Singapore, or
operating subsidiaries in relatively small markets. In principle, the application of the BALRM should also limit US taxation of foreignowned TNCs Carlson, Fogarasi
Gordon 1988, and this is becoming more significant as the growth of direct investment into the USA continues to even out the previous imbalance. However, this
would depend on the willingness of the US authorities to accept that foreignowned subsidiaries in the US do not own significant intangibles. It is more likely that due to
the size and complexity of the US market, foreignowned companies would be regarded as substantially distinct operations from their parents, thus justifying an
allocation to them of an appropriate proportion of the residual profits. Equally, the other main OECD countries may also argue that there is a difference between major
TNC affiliates with substantial operations and their own independent knowhow, and smaller subsidiaries operating in restricted markets, or carrying out specific functions
of a `contract manufacturer
¶kind. The rate of return method based on functional analysis represents a significant retreat
from the attempt to adjust prices of individual transactions mainly by finding comparables. It may be that the identification of functions will provide a more precise
and flexible basis for evaluating profit than other `empirical ¶methods that have been
used, such as gross margin on sales. It also makes it explicit that, at least in the case of integrated, researchbased TNCs, there is likely to be a significant element of
`residual ¶ profit attributable to the organization as such, which must either be
assigned to the parent, or allocated among the main affiliates according to some measure of their contributions to the innovations and risks of the organization. But it
1
The official foreign government responses to the White Paper were confidential and not published, although many of the relevant officials have expressed their personal views in symposia: see e.g. De
Hosson ed 1989.
does not resolve many of the problems which historically made the tax authorities fight shy of explicitly adopting a profitsplit method. Hence, it is not much help in
evaluating the profit split between the related parties: by focussing on `measurable ¶
functions, it merely assumes that synergy profits accrue to the ultimate parent. Due to their broader political and economic implications, there is likely to be
continued reluctance to tackle these questions explicitly and publicly, and a continuing insistence that the normal and primary test of transfer prices is that of
independent parties dealing at arms length. Indeed, the White Paper was fiercely criticised by the Taxation Commission of the International Chamber of Commerce, as
entailing `fundamental deviations from the arms length principle
¶ Professor Wolfgang Ritter, responding to the White Paper on behalf of that Commission, wrote
that the Basic Arms Length Return Method: is nothing but another form of unitary taxation, now recognised by the US
Federal Authorities, as a result of the international outcry which it provoked, to be unfair. BALRM analysis does exactly what unitary taxation does:
instead of looking at the actual prices charged between related entities, it looks at the total profits earned by a number of entities and divides them up
by reference to criteria determined by academic economists with no experience of the real business world. Ritter, in De Hosson 1989, p.73.
4. Transfer Prices in Theory and Practice