TRANSACTIONS CLASSIFICATIONS So far we have defined the important summary measures of the balance of

TRANSACTIONS CLASSIFICATIONS So far we have defined the important summary measures of the balance of

payments and have developed an understanding of the various categories included in a nation’s international transactions. The actual classification of transactions is often confusing to those first considering such issues. To aid in understanding these classification problems, we will analyze six transac- tions and their placement in a simplified U.S. balance of payments.

First, we must remember that the balance of payments is a balance sheet, so, at the bottom line, total credits equal total debits. This means that we use double-entry bookkeeping—every item involves two entries,

a credit and a debit, to the balance sheet. The credits record items leading to inflows of payments. Such items are associated with a greater demand for domestic currency or supply of foreign currency to the foreign exchange market. The debits record items that lead to payments outflows. These are associated with a greater supply of domestic currency or demand for foreign currency in the foreign exchange market. Now con- sider the following six hypothetical transactions and their corresponding entries in Table 3.2 .

1. A U.S. bank makes a loan of $1 million to a Romanian food proces- sor. The loan is funded by creating a $1 million deposit for the Romanian firm in the U.S. bank. The loan represents a private capital

70 International Money and Finance

Table 3.2 Balance of Payments

Debit (2) Net balance Merchandise

Services $10,000 (4) Investment income

Unilateral transfers 100,000 (5) Current account

$1,000,000 Official capital

$50,000,000 (6) Private capital

Note: The numbers in parentheses refer to the six transactions we have analyzed.

we credit merchandise $1 million. Payment using the deposit results in the decrease of foreign-owned deposits in U.S. banks; this is treated as

a capital outflow, leading to a $1 million debit to private capital.

3. A U.S. resident receives $10,000 in interest from German bonds she owns. The $10,000 is deposited in a German bank. Earnings on inter- national foreign investments represent a credit to the investment income account. The increase in U.S.-owned foreign bank deposits is considered a capital outflow and is recorded by debiting private capital in the amount of $10,000.

4. A U.S. tourist travels to Europe and spends the $10,000 German deposit. Tourist spending is recorded in the services account. U.S. tourist spending abroad is recorded as a $10,000 debit to the services account. The decrease in U.S.-owned foreign deposits is considered a private capital inflow and is recorded by a $10,000 credit to private capital.

5. The United States government gives $100,000 worth of grain to Nicaragua. The grain export is recorded as a $100,000 credit to the merchandise account. Since the grain was a gift, the balancing entry is unilateral transfers; in this case, there is a debit of $100,000 to unilat-

The Balance of Payments 71

treated as a capital outflow; but, since the deposit was owned by a for- eign government, there is a $50 million debit to official capital. Note that the current account balance is the sum of the merchandise,

services, investment income, and unilateral transfers accounts. Summing the credits and debits, we find that the credits sum to $1,110,000, whereas the debits sum to $110,000, so that there is a positive, or credit, balance of $1 million on the current account.

The capital entries are typically the most confusing, particularly those relating to changes in bank deposits. For instance, the third transaction we analyzed recorded the deposit of $10,000 in a German bank as a debit to the private capital account of the United States. The fourth transaction recorded the U.S. tourist’s spending of the $10,000 German bank deposit as a credit to the private capital account of the United States. This may seem confusing because early in the chapter it was suggested that credit items are items that bring foreign exchange into a country, while debit items involve foreign exchange leaving the country. But neither of these transactions affected bank deposits in the United States, just foreign depos- its. The key is to think of the deposit of $10,000 in a German bank as money that had come from a U.S. bank account. Increases in U.S.-owned deposits in foreign banks are debits whether or not the money was ever in the United States. What matters is not whether the money is ever physi- cally in the United States, but the country of residence of the owner. Similarly, decreases in U.S.-owned foreign deposits are recorded as a credit to private capital, whether or not the money is actually brought from abroad to the United States.

The item called “statistical discrepancy” (line 69) in Figure 3.1 is not the result of not knowing where to classify some transactions. The interna- tional transactions that are recorded are simply difficult to measure accurately. Taking the numbers from customs records and surveys of busi- ness firms will not capture all of the trade actually occurring. Some of this may be due to illegal or underground activity, but in the modern dynamic economy we would expect sizable measurement errors even with no ille- gal activity. It is simply impossible to observe every transaction, so we

72 International Money and Finance

economic implications of the balance of payments. For instance, since merchandise exports earn foreign exchange while imports involve out- flows of foreign exchange, we often hear arguments for policy aimed at maximizing the trade or current account surplus. Is this in fact desirable? First, it must be realized that, because one country’s export is another’s import, it is impossible for everyone to have surpluses. On a worldwide basis, the total value of exports equals the total value of imports—that is, there is globally balanced trade. Actually, the manner in which trade data are collected imparts a surplus bias to trade balances. Exports are recorded when goods are shipped, while imports are recorded upon receipt. Because there are always goods in transit from the exporter to the importer, if we sum the balance of trade for all nations we would expect

a global trade surplus. However, the global current account balance has summed to a deficit in recent years. The problem seems to involve the difficulty of accurately measuring international financial transactions. Merchandise trade can be measured fairly accurately, and the global sum of trade balances is roughly zero; but, service transactions are more diffi- cult to observe, and investment income flows seem to be the major source of global current account discrepancies. The problem arises because countries receiving capital inflows (the debtors) more accurately record the value received than the resident countries of the creditors. For instance, if an investor in Singapore bought shares of stock in Mexico, the government of Mexico is more likely to observe accurately the transaction than is the government of Singapore. Yet even with these bookkeeping problems facing government statisticians, the essential eco- nomic point of one country’s deficit being another’s surplus is still true.

Since one country must always have a trade deficit if another has a trade surplus, is it necessarily true that surpluses are good and deficits bad and that one country benefits at another’s expense? In one sense, it would seem that imports should be preferred to exports. In terms of current consumption, merchandise exports represent goods that will be consumed by foreign impor- ters and is no longer available for domestic consumption. As we learn from studying international trade theory, the benefits of free international trade are

The Balance of Payments 73

In general, it is not obvious whether a country is better or worse off if it runs payments surpluses rather than deficits. Consider the following simple example of a world with two countries, A and B. Country A is a wealthy creditor country that has extended loans to poor country B. In order for country B to repay these loans, B must run trade surpluses with

A to earn the foreign exchange required for repayment. Would you rather live in rich country A and experience trade deficits or in poor country B and experience trade surpluses? Although this is indeed a simplistic exam- ple, there are real-world analogues of rich creditor countries with trade deficits and poor debtor nations with trade surpluses. The point here is that you cannot analyze the balance of payments apart from other economic considerations. Deficits are not inherently bad, nor are surpluses necessarily good.

Balance of payments equilibrium is often thought of as a condition in which exports equal imports or credits equal debits on some particular subaccount, like the current account or the official settlements account. In fact, countries can have an equilibrium balance on the current account that is positive, negative, or zero, depending upon what circumstances are sustainable over time. For instance, a current account deficit will be the equilibrium for the United States if the rest of the world wants to accu- mulate U.S. financial assets. This involves a U.S. capital account surplus as U.S. financial assets are sold to foreign buyers, which will be matched by

a current account deficit. So equilibrium need not be a zero balance. However, to simplify the next analysis, let’s assume that equilibrium is associated with a zero balance. In this sense, if we had a current account equilibrium, then the nation would find its net creditor or debtor posi- tion unchanging since there is no need for any net financing—the current account export items are just balanced by the current account import items. Equilibrium on the official settlements basis would mean no change in short-term capital held by foreign monetary agencies and reserve assets. For most countries, this would simply mean that their stocks of international reserves would be unchanging.

What happens if there is a disequilibrium in the balance of

74 International Money and Finance

essentially the case for most countries), let us consider foreign exchange alone. The concept of balance of payments equilibrium is linked to the supply and demand diagram presented in Chapters 1 and 2. In the case of flexible exchange rates, where the exchange rate is determined by free mar- ket supply and demand, balance of payments equilibrium is restored by the operation of the free market. Therefore, the official settlements account will be zero. In contrast, as we have learned in Chapter 2, exchange rates are not always free to adjust to changing market conditions. With fixed exchange rates, central banks set exchange rates at a particular level. When the exchange rate is fixed the dollar can be overva- lued or undervalued and the central banks must now finance the trade imbalance by international reserve flows. Specifically, in the case of a trade deficit, the Federal Reserve sells foreign currency for dollars. In this case, the U.S. trade deficit could continue only as long as the stock of for- eign currency lasts and the official settlements balance will show such an intervention.

Besides these methods of adjusting a balance of payments disequilibrium, countries sometimes use direct controls on international trade, such as government-mandated quotas or prices, to shift the supply and demand curves and induce balance of payments equilibrium. Such policies are particularly popular in developing countries where chronic shortages of international reserves do not permit financing the free-mar- ket-determined trade disequilibrium at the government-supported exchange rate.

The mechanism of adjustment to balance of payments equilibrium is one of the most important practical problems in international economics. The discussion here is but an introduction; much of the analysis of Chapters 12, 13, 14 and 15 is related to this issue as well.

THE U.S. FOREIGN DEBT One implication of capital account transactions, in Table 3.1 , is the

The Balance of Payments 75

U.S. securities led to a rapid drop in the net creditor position of the U.S. in 1982 to a net debtor status by 1986.

The detailed net international investment position is provided in Table 3.3 . One can think of Table 3.3 as a sum of Table 3.1 , reflecting the net position of the U.S. vis-a`-vis the rest of the world at any given time. In contrast, Table 3.1 shows the flow of goods and service during a particular year. The first line in Table 3.3 shows the cumulative net investment position. It shows that the U.S. was the largest creditor in the world in the 1970s and early 1980s, but in the 1980s the net position started to deteriorate, and the U.S. became the biggest debtor nation in the world with a net position in 2010 of 2$2,470,989 million. Thus, for- eigners have almost $2.5 trillion in claims on U.S. assets in excess of the U.S. claims on foreign assets.

The detailed accounts are also of interest. There is an enormous amount of claims on foreign assets held by U.S. residents. Over $20 tril- lion worth of claims on foreign assets are held by U.S. residents, whereas foreigners hold about $22.5 trillion in claims. In comparison, the U.S. GDP for the U.S. in 2010 was close to 15 trillion. So the international asset holdings exceed the U.S. GDP.

Recall from Table 3.1 that the current account deficit results in for- eigners adding more claims on U.S. assets. The U.S. net international investment position is a sum of all the past current account deficits and surpluses. Thus, the current account is a useful measure because it sum- marizes the trend with regard to the net debtor position of a country. For this reason, international bankers focus on the current account trend as one of the crucial variables to consider when evaluating loans to foreign countries.

HOW BAD IS THE U.S. FOREIGN DEBT? In the last section we concluded that the U.S. owes almost $2.5 trillion

more than it has in receivables from the rest of the world. How serious is this? We hear a lot about the U.S. federal debt, but rarely about the U.S.

Table 3.3 U.S. Net International Investment Position Line

Type of Investment

1 Net international investment

61,739 2230,375 2430,194 21,337,014 21,932,149 22,470,989 position of the United States (lines 2 1 3)

2 Financial derivatives, net (line 5 less 57,915 110,421 line 25) 3 Net international investment position,

61,739 2230,375 2430,194 21,337,014 21,990,064 22,581,410 excluding financial derivatives (line 6 less line 26)

4 U.S.-owned assets abroad (lines

5 Financial derivatives (gross positive fair 1,190,029 3,652,909 value) 6 U.S.-owned assets abroad, excluding

6,238,785 10,771,523 16,662,450 financial derivatives (lines 7 1 12 1 17) 7 US. official reserve assets

71,799 134,175 367,537 9 Special drawing rights

10,539 8,210 56,824 10 Reserve position in the International

14,824 8,036 12,492 Monetary Fund 11 Foreign currencies

31,238 37,622 51,820 12 U.S. government assets, other than

85,168 77,523 75,235 official reserve assets 13 U.S. credits and other long-term assets

82,574 76,960 74,399 14 Repayable in dollars

Table 3.3 (Continued) Line

Type of Investment

281 273 273 16 U.S. foreign currency holdings and U.S.

2,594 563 836 short-term assets 17 U.S. private assets

6,025,217 10,505,957 16,098,542 18 Direct investment at current cost

1,531,607 2,651,721 4,429,426 19 Foreign securities

572,692 1,011,554 1,737,271 21 Corpora te stocks

1,852,842 3,317,705 4,485,593 22 U.S. claims on unaffiliated foreigners

836,559 1,018,462 873,667 reported by U.S. nonbanking concerns 23 U.S. claims reported by U.S. banks and

1,231,517 2,506,515 4,572,585 securities brokers, not included elsewhere

7,575,799 13,893,701 22,786,348 States (lines 25 1 26) 25 Financial derivatives (gross negative fair

24 Foreign-owned assets in the United

1,132,114 3,542,488 value) 26 Foreign-owned assets in the United

7,575,799 12,761,587 19,243,860 States, excluding financial derivatives (lines 27 1 34)

1,037,092 2,313,295 4,863,623 28 U.S. government securities

27 Foreign official assets in the United States 107,110 181,217

756,155 1,725,193 3,957,204 29 U.S. Treasury securities

639,796 1,340,598 3,320,694 30 Other

116,359 384,595 636,510 (Continued)

Table 3.3 (Continued) Line

Type of Investment

25,700 22,869 110,243 32 U.S. liabilities reported by U.S. banks and 17,231 30,381

31 Other U.S. government liabilities

153,403 296,647 178,107 securities brokers, not included elsewhere

101,834 268,586 618,069 34 Other foreign assets

33 Other foreign official assets

6,538,707 10,448,292 14,380,237 35 Direct investment at current cost

1,421,017 1,905,979 2,658,932 36 U.S. Treasury securities

381,630 643,793 1,064,594 37 U.S. securities other than U.S. Treasury

2,623,014 4,352,998 5,860,093 securities 38 Corporate and other bonds

1,068,566 2,243,135 2,868,460 39 Corporate stocks

1,554,448 2,109,863 2,991,633 40 U.S. currency

205,406 280,400 342,090 41 U.S. liabilities to unaffiliated foreigners

738,904 658,177 747,795 reported by U.S. nonbanking concerns 42 U.S. liabilities reported by U.S. banks and 53,465 121,069

1,168,736 2,606,945 3,706,733 securities brokers, not included elsewhere

Memoranda: 43 Direct investment abroad at market value

2,694,014 3,637,996 4,843,325 44 Direct investment in the United States at

2,783,235 2,817,970 3,451,405 market value

p Preliminary.

The Balance of Payments 79

34 show more direct investments in foreign countries by U.S. residents, whereas foreigners tend to own more bonds in the U.S. Both of these reasons cause the return to assets held by foreigners in the U.S. to be low relative to the return for U.S. residents’ investments abroad. In fact, although the U.S. owes $2.5 trillion more than foreigners owe the U.S., the return on U.S. investments is so much higher that the total net income from assets held by U.S. residents in other countries exceeds the return by foreigners’ holdings of U.S. assets. We can see that by looking back at the income receipts and payments in Figure 3.1 . The income receipts in 2010 were $663 billion, line (12), and the payments were $498, line (29). Thus, the U.S. generated a net income surplus of $165 billion even though the asset base was much smaller for the U.S. Thus, the international debt is not a burden from the income perspective.

In addition, it should be noted that the $2.5 trillion of net U.S. debt is different from a developing country debt. The U.S. international debt is owed in dollars, thus the only payments foreign holders of assets receive are dollar balances. These are easy to pay back for a country that prints dollar balances. In contrast, a developing country debt is, usually, in U.S. dollars also. However, in a country that does not print U.S. dollars it is harder to generate enough balances to pay the debt back.