Estimation Results Manajemen | Fakultas Ekonomi Universitas Maritim Raja Ali Haji 839.full_2

The Journal of Human Resources 852 sample is random and negligible. Here this is not feasible because of the criteria used to select the spells. Note that when we are estimating a model in which the explanatory variables and the unobserved components are independent, we can still make inferences about the model parameters even if the proportional hazard model is misspecified. In this case the coefficients will be biased toward zero but the standard errors are approximately correct see Lancaster 1990. We work with a data set that has only one spell per individual in order to avoid problems of correlation between observations from the same individual that result from unobserved heterogeneity. Under the assumption that the unobserved compo- nents are random and uncorrelated across individuals and that the observed and unob- served components are independent, we can satisfy the distribution restriction placed on the error term by the proportional hazard model. This spell is randomly selected from the set of spells for each individual that “sur- vived” the selection criteria mentioned in the data section. This results in a sample of 2,688 observations, 13 percent of which are censored. We have also estimated the same model using several observations per worker. The results obtained using all the observations were qualitatively similar to those reported in the next section, as were those obtained by applying Chamberlain’s criteria to the selection of the observations. The problems associated with the process of sample construction in studies of the impact of UI, namely on UI duration, were addressed in several papers, an example being Portugal and Addison 1990. One of the most important issues of sample selec- tion relates to the impact of UI on the search behavior on the part of the unemployed. The procedures described above try to cope with these problems of sample selection biases. For example, the use of an imputed UI benefit for the nonrecipients follows a suggestion of Portugal and Addison 1990, and makes the UI benefit variable exoge- nous to UI receipt, thus avoiding simultaneity problems. However, other issues related with sample selection biases might still be present. In an attempt to check our basic findings’ robustness, we report results from estimating the main model for a sample on noneligible workers. As these workers might have different expected search bene- fits under the UI program, the impact of UI generosity must have a smaller impact on post-unemployment outcomes for this group of workers.

V. Estimation Results

Tables 2 and 3 present the results of the parameter estimation from different proportional hazard model specifications using the NLSY79 panel and the criteria described in Sections III and IV to define the sample composition. The coefficients of interest are those on the state monthly unemployment rate at the beginning of the spell, the measure of the UI benefit either the simulated or the max- imum benefit, and the interaction between these two terms. 10 Other covariates were also included in all specifications of the model. Their coefficients are not presented in 10. The unemployment rate and the UI benefit measure are included as deviations from the sample means. This implies that the impact of each variable is being evaluated at the sample mean since the interaction would then be zero. Centeno 853 Table 3 Estimates for the Proportional Hazard Model—NLSY79 Eligible Workers Sample. Risk Variable: Tenure on the Job Measure of UI System: Log Maximum Weekly State Unemployment Benefit Log Log Unemployment Log Unemployment Log Wald Starting Region of Starting Rate at Start Simulated Rate Log Starting X 2 df Month Residence Year Equation of Job UIB Simulated UIB Wage Statistic Dummy Dummy Dummy N 1 0.2658 −0.3490 123 26 24No No No 2,367 0.0752 0.0562 2 0.3135 −0.5153 −0.3367 141 27 No No No 2,367 0.0753 0.1145 0.0561 3 0.4637 −0.4533 −1.6217 −0.3322 181 28 No No No 2,367 0.0790 0.1146 0.3309 0.0548 4 0.0319 −0.3175 280 59 Yes Yes Yes 2,367 0.1001 0.0549 5 0.1063 −0.4142 −0.3093 292 60 Yes Yes Yes 2,367 0.1014 0.1248 0.0547 6 0.2651 −0.3468 −1.4628 −0.3024 321 61 Yes Yes Yes 2,367 0.1044 0.1262 0.3431 0.0542 Data are composed of a panel of workers from the NLSY79 over the period 1979–98. The generosity of the unemployment insurance system is measured by the maximum state unemployment benefit. Variables are defined in Section III. Covariates included in each regression are 11 industry dummies and 10 occupation dummies. Additional covariates included in each regression are high school graduate, college graduate, marital status, white and union status dummies. Standard errors are in parentheses. They are corrected to allow for group effects within state-year cells. N is the sample size. Tables 2 and 3 because they do not vary significantly across specifications. In Table A2 in the Appendix we present the full set of results for two of the model specifica- tions of Table 2. These estimates are in line with what is found in the literature on job tenure see, for example, Farber 1999: white, married and more educated workers experience longer employment spells, and workers with union covered contracts have longer expected tenure. In Table 2 the first specification for each model tests the procyclicality of match dura- tion. As previously found, there is a negative effect of the cycle on the quality of matches—jobs initiated during booms last longer than those initiated during recessions. In Table 2 the simulated UI benefit is used to measure the generosity of the UI sys- tem. In Line 2 we add the log of the maximum state UI benefit. The negative coeffi- cient implies that higher UI benefits reduce the employment hazard, leading to longer expected match tenure. However, the main test of our hypotheses is carried out in Line 3, adding the interaction term between the unemployment rate and the UI benefit measure. The impact of the UI benefit evaluated at the mean log unemployment rate is −0.723 t-statistic equal to −7.298, indicating that higher benefits decrease the probability of a job being terminated. The estimated effect of the log unemployment rate, evaluated at the mean log simulated UI benefit, is 0.293 with a t-ratio equal to 3.690, meaning that higher state unemployment rates at the start of the match lead to shorter job tenures and match quality has a procyclical behavior. These results seem to support one of the hypotheses being tested, namely that higher UI benefits tend to reduce the employment hazard rate over the business cycle. The second hypothesis is related to the effect that higher UI benefits have in the cyclical behavior of match quality. If the cyclicality of match quality is related to the congestion pressure, one can investigate whether the UI system is more effective in attenuating this pressure during recessions or during booms. This hypothesis is related to the sign of the interaction coefficient. The estimates in Table 2 imply that the UI benefit system has a greater impact on the employment hazard at higher levels of the unemployment rate the interaction term is negative. This result can also be inter- preted as the UI system having the effect of knocking the cyclical behavior of match quality out. It is an indication that the reduction on the congestion pressure operated through the UI system is more effective in recessions than in booms, and implies that UI benefits smooth out the cyclical pattern of match quality. In order to test the possibility that these results are driven by factors other than the effect of the UI benefit, we estimated alternative specifications of the model. One pos- sible effect is through initial wages. It might be that the labor market internalizes most of the cycle and reservation wage effects through initial wages, such that after con- trolling for the initial wage the effect of the cycle and of UI benefits is knocked out. In Lines 4–6 we include the starting wage. The results show that the impact of the UI benefit is only slightly reduced to −0.627 and is still significantly different from zero. The unemployment rate coefficient is also smaller, equal to 0.185, but remains statis- tically significant. The effect of the starting wages in the probability of a spell being terminated points to the importance of including more controls in the model specifi- cation in order to eliminate, or at least reduce, further omitted variable bias. 11 11. In Bowlus 1995 the starting wage has a much greater impact on the coefficient for the unemployment rate at the start of the job. The difference between the results can be twofold. First, the results in Table 2 The Journal of Human Resources 854 Next, we control for seasonal as opposed to cyclical patterns by including dummy variables indicating the starting month of the employment spell Lines 7–9. The sta- tistical significance of the simulated UI benefit effect on the hazard rate does not change much. In fact, the marginal effect remains quite stable for the UI measure it changes from −0.627 to −0.551. On the contrary, the coefficient of the unemployment rate is further reduced to 0.130, and is now not statistically different from zero. The coefficient on the starting wage decreases slightly. An analysis of the distribution of high UI benefit states shows that they are dispro- portionately concentrated in the Midwest and Northeast while low UI benefits states are located mainly in the South. We include region dummies to control for regional effects Lines 10–12 trying to identify time invariant regional differences for exam- ple, differences in productivity that affect both starting wages and spell durations. Again, the results did change significantly, neither for the unemployment rate nor for the UI benefit. 12 Of more consequential impact on the results was the inclusion of year dummies Lines 13–15 of Table 2. These are meant to capture time effects due to the evolution of job tenure and UI generosity. The estimated impact of the UI benefit is much less, estimated at −0.335 and statistically significant a t-ratio of −2.867. The year dum- mies might be capturing the opposite trends of job tenure and UI generosity observed in the sample. 13 Note also that the coefficient on the starting unemployment rate is no longer statistically significant in Specification 13. This result might be an indication of differences in match cyclical behavior between the 1980s and ’90s and that are cap- tured through the year dummies. Taken together, these results might imply a policy interpretation that state governments use the UI benefit in recession years as a social subsidy. This effect will be reflected in the year dummies, and the UI benefit again has the reservation wage interpretation. Finally, we present a model with month, region, and year controls. The results for this model are shown in Lines 16–18. In Model 18, the coefficient estimate for the UI measure is smaller, but the t-statistic −2.23 still provides support for the hypothesis that UI generosity increases the duration of job tenure upon unemployment. However, in this model, there is only weak evidence in favor of the dampening effect of UI on the cyclical variation in match quality. In Table 3 we present the results obtained replacing the simulated UI benefit with the maximum state UI benefit for Specifications 6 and 18 in Table 2. The results cover a much larger period twice as many years and two complete business cycles. Secondly, and more important, the sample selection criteria are quite different in the two papers. While Bowlus used all employ- ment spells in the NLSY79, we are only considering post-unemployment spells, further restricting them to jobs following unemployment experiences in which the worker was eligible to receive UI benefits. We can argue that the overall effect of the cycle through wages that operates at a general level might not be present in a sample of displaced workers, whose wages tend to be lower and more affected by the reservation wage effect of the UI benefit. In fact, from recent work by Barlevy 2001 we have learned that wage cyclicality is lower in high UI states, a fact consistent with the above results. Furthermore, using Bowlus’ sample selec- tion criteria, we find the starting wages to have a much greater impact on the estimated coefficient for unem- ployment. Thus, the difference in the results could be based on a different cyclical behavior of wages and match tenure for laid-off workers experiencing unemployment. 12. Results with state fixed effects did not change the basic results obtained with region fixed effects. 13. In our sample, average tenure falls over the sample period from 97 weeks to 76 weeks, while the real simulated UI benefit increases from 63 USD to around 90 USD by the end of the period. Centeno 855 obtained with the maximum benefit are supportive of the two hypotheses being tested. However, it is worth noting that in Table 3 the statistical significance of the coeffi- cients is much higher than the one obtained using the simulated UI, in particular for the interaction coefficient. A possible interpretation for these differences is that the maximum UI benefit is capturing something about the state economy or the state’s UI policy that it should not, as mentioned in the Data section, and that motivated the use of the simulated UI benefit. 14 As a robustness check on these results, we estimated the main model for a sample of noneligible workers. These workers might have lower expected search benefits under the UI program and, as a consequence, the impact of UI generosity on post- unemployment outcomes should be smaller or even negligible. The employment spells included in the noneligibles sample were those following an unemployment spell in which the individual was not eligible to receive UI, either because the worker quit the previous job or because the number of weeks of work during the previous year did not reach the minimum required for the worker to be eligible for UI. The results from the estimation of these models are reported in Table 4. For the sample of workers noneligible to receive UI, after the inclusion of the month, region and starting year dummies, the impact of UI on job tenure is not statistically different from zero and the UI does not have any sizable impact on the cyclicality of match quality. Despite the fact that the magnitude of the estimated coefficients in Tables 2 and 4 is not statistically dif- ferent, match tenure for noneligible workers seems to be unaffected by UI. From the proportional hazard model coefficients one cannot tell the magnitude of the impact of the UI system generosity on job tenure. In order to be able to evaluate the magnitude of the estimated effects in Table 2 we compute two alternative indica- tors. First, we estimate the shift in the baseline survivor function in response to an increase in UI generosity. Next, we use the conditional cumulative density function of the proportional hazard model and estimate median tenures for different values of the UI system measure. The baseline survivor function t exp S t u du λ = - gives us the probability of a match surviving just beyond time t, when the covariates in X are all set at zero. We start by evaluating the baseline survivor function at the mean values of the simulated UI, the unemployment rate and the starting wage, for a single, black, high-school graduate worker with a nonunion contract. 15 Having estimated the baseline survivor function, we can use it to obtain estimates of the survivor function for any covariate vector X using | . S t X S t exp X = βl t In Table 5, we evaluate the survivor function shift in response to an increase in UI generosity, at different values of tenure. We study the impact on the survival proba- bility of increasing the simulated UI benefit: in the second column we report the impact of a 10 percent increase 0.1 change in log UIB and in the third column, a standard deviation increase a 0.316 change in log UIB. 14. We performed several tests of the proportional hazard specification. In all these tests the results con- firmed the correctness of the proportional hazard model assumption. 15. Table A3 in the Appendix reports the estimates of the baseline survivor function for different values of tenure, using the results from Model 18 in Table 2. The Journal of Human Resources 856 Centeno 857 Table 4 Estimates for the Proportional Hazard Model—NLSY79 Sample. Robustness Check: Noneligible Sample. Risk Variable: Tenure on the Job. Measure of UI System: Log Simulated Weekly State Unemployment Benefit Log Log Unemployment Log Unemployment Log Wald Starting Region of Starting Rate at Start Simulated Rate Log Starting X 2 df Month Residence Year of Job UIB Simulated UIB Wage Statistic Dummy Dummy Dummy N 0.2259 −0.3466 −0.1484 −0.3110 554 25 No No No 3,747 0.0480 0.0563 0.2117 0.0237 0.1243 −0.0808 −0.3236 −0.2997 693 61 Yes Yes Yes 3,747 0.0569 0.0929 0.2294 0.0242 Data are composed of a panel of workers from the NLSY79 over the period 1979–98. The generosity of the unemployment insurance system is measured by the simulated weekly state unemployment benefit. Variables are defined in Section III. Covariates included in each regression are 11 industry dummies and 10 occupation dummies. Additional covariates included in each regression are high school graduate, college graduate, marital status, white, and union status dummies. Standard errors are in paren- theses. They are corrected to allow for group effects within state-year cells. N is the sample size. The results show that at the mean value of tenure 95 weeks the survival probabil- ity increases by three percentage points in response to a standard deviation increase in the simulated UI benefit from its mean value all other variables remaining at their original values. The shift in survival probability is of a reasonable magnitude given that most new jobs in the U.S. labor market end early in the relationship, especially during their first year see Farber 1999. An alternative measure to evaluate the UI impact on match tenure consists in esti- mating median tenure for different values of UI generosity. To do that we use the baseline survivor function estimated above and set the conditional cumulative density function equal to 0.5 as follows: | . exp F t X e S t 1 0 5 X = - - = βl t ` j Using the estimated βs and setting the explanatory variables at the desired values we can back out a level for the integrated hazard function that is associated with the median tenure for that model specification. Using the results from Model 18 in Table 2 and considering the same base values for the covariates as above, median tenure is 57 weeks for an unemployment rate equal to 6.6 percent and a simulated UI equal to 75 USD their mean values. If we increase the simulated UI by 10 percent, median tenure increases to 59 weeks, while with a standard deviation increase of the UI mea- The Journal of Human Resources 858 Table 5 Impact on Survival Probability of an Increase in Unemployment Insurance Benefit Generosity Estimates based on Model 18 from Table 2 Baseline Simulated UI Increase Equal to Survival One Standard At Tenure Function 10 percent Deviation Equal to 1 2 3 26 weeks 0.7129 0.0062 0.0192 52 weeks 0.5347 0.0086 0.0269 78 weeks 0.4019 0.0095 0.0298 95 weeks mean tenure 0.3537 0.0095 0.0301 104 weeks 0.3348 0.0095 0.0300 156 weeks 0.2305 0.0088 0.0282 260 weeks 0.1319 0.0070 0.0227 The baseline survivor function for a given time t gives us the probability of a match surviving just beyond that time t and is reported in Column 1. The baseline survivor function is evaluated at the mean values of the unemployment rate, the UI measure and the starting wage. Other relevant characteristics are: nonunion, black, high school graduate and single worker. The table presents the shift in survival probabilities at differ- ent levels of tenure. The figures in Columns 2 and 3 correspond to the increase in estimated survival proba- bility when we increase UI generosity from its baseline value by 0.1 and 0.316, respectively. sure, median tenure is equal to 61 weeks. The impact is an increase in duration equal to four weeks for each standard deviation increase of the UI benefit measure. Overall, the evidence presented lends some support to the hypotheses being tested. On the one hand, there is evidence that higher UI benefits tend to increase the dura- tion of subsequent employment spells, and on the other hand, we find some limited evidence that more generous benefits reduce the cyclicality of job match quality, the impact on employment duration is greater, the higher the unemployment rate.

VI. Conclusions