Inter State Internal Migration State lev

1
Inter-State Internal Migration: State-level Wellbeing as a Cause
Abstract
The relationship between subjective wellbeing and in-migration is explored in this paper. The wellbeing of
a state is considered an incentive for in-migration to that state as the wellbeing in that state increases. A crosssectional, multiple regression on the contiguous states in the United States was used to determine if there is any
relationship. A significant and positive relationship was found between state-level subjective wellbeing and net inmigration when controlling for economic and non-economic variables typically associated with in-migration. The
positive relationship indicates that as a state’s wellbeing increases its appeal as a destination for internal migrants
increases as well. It is recommended for policymakers to focus on improving the subjective wellbeing of their
state’s residents not only to retain and attract new residents, but as a general measure of successful administration.
Future studies are needed to verify the link between a state’s wellbeing and in-migration to that state. This study
serves as a first step in this literature.
Keywords:
Internal migration, Subjective wellbeing, Migration incentives, State-level wellbeing, State net in-migration
Introduction
A distinction needs to be made between happiness or wellbeing, a more comprehensive and broader
expression of happiness, and utility. Utility is measured by individual preferences (Frey & Stutzer 2000). In regards
to happiness, utility is defined by average happiness and the length of life of people. Much like general happiness,
utility is about making people happier with a focus on the choices that improve net happiness (Brϋlde 2010). The
main difference between utility and general happiness is the inclusion of both pecuniary aspects such as income and
non-pecuniary aspects such as job satisfaction (Easterlin 2003). Veenhoven (2000) labels the differences as
objective and subjective wellbeing. Objective wellbeing is related to income and subjective wellbeing is related to

one’s state of mind.
Objective wellbeing is a standard used in traditional economic measures of success such as per capita
income or gross domestic product (Eckersley 2009). The underlying assumption is that as one’s income increases or
the general gross domestic product increases the wellbeing of the individual citizen increases along with it. The
refocus on subjective wellbeing in contrast to these measures of wellbeing has challenged this traditional
assumption. There has been a push to abandon these traditional measures of progress and utilize the subjective

2
wellbeing scales as a measure of progress. Some countries have even adopted it as a measure of success for
governmental policies such as Bhutan and its Gross National Happiness scale.
There are some challenges to measuring subjective wellbeing, however there have been some very
comprehensive measures of it such as the Gallup-Healthways Wellbeing Index, which interviews at least 1000
random adult respondents across the fifty states and different congressional districts on a daily basis. It is one large
index composed of six smaller indexes. These indexes measure life evaluation, emotional health, physical health,
healthy behavior, work environment and basic access. The life evaluation index captures the evaluation of the
respondents’ present life situation and the respondents anticipated life situation five years from the time of the
survey. The emotional health index asks about the respondent’s thoughts about the day before on various indicators
of emotional health such as whether they were treated with respect or if they were happy or sad. The physical health
index gathers data on estimates on BMI, disease burdens, sick days used and physical pain amongst other factors.
The healthy behavior index similarly captures the effects of health on the wellbeing of a person through responses

on lifestyle habits such as smoking and eating right. The work environment index includes feelings and perceptions
about the respondent’s work environment such as satisfaction with their work. The basic access index is concerned
with satisfaction with the community, access to clean water, the feeling of safety and access to adequate levels of
money for food and shelter as well as access to health insurance amongst other factors (Gallup-Healthways 2009).
It is not difficult to imagine how state-level policymaking in the United States can have an impact on most
of the indexes covered in the Gallup-Healthways Wellbeing Index. Some states have committed to anti-smoking
campaigns and encouraging their population to eat right. States also have power over access to medical care through
state-level policy control over Medicaid and other forms of health insurance. State legislation can also impact the
work environment both public and private through regulations that impact benefits, pay, etc. States also contribute
significant funds to their local governments to improve public safety and clean water in addition to state-level efforts
in these areas. In essence, states in the United States have a lot of control over those areas that have been considered
critical to improving individual wellbeing so there can be some differences between states on individual wellbeing.
In addition, the United States allows for the free flow of people between states in which some states are
gaining population while some states are losing population. In addition, given that the United States is a federalized
country which gives significant discretion and autonomy to its states and local governments the reliance on ownsource revenues in these lower levels of government is quite substantial. These revenues are linked either to sales,

3
income or property for the most part and require a critical mass of population particularly those in the middle to
upper income brackets to sustain services to the population. A loss in population, especially the middle class since
the bulk of the population is in this class category, would signal a fiscal dilemma where the costs of service

provision rarely adjust to a declining population. This also signals a growing percentage of those who are poor who
are unable to migrate and who require greater services. The problem becomes self-reinforcing when population loss
fuels more population loss in which state decision-makers become more constrained in the choices available to them
to address the problems.
Traditionally, government in the United States at all levels has assumed that the key to wellbeing is purely
economic. In this regards, migration to one state or another would be based on the economic benefits received from
the migration i.e. better net income per capita. In general, the literature on internal migration in the United States
has focused on this cause, however it has also included non-pecuniary aspects as well (Cebula & Nair-Reichert
2012; Ashby 2007; Conway & Houtenville 2003; Reisinger 2003; Davanzo 1978; Treyz, Rickman, Hunt &
Greenwood 1993; Cebula 2005; Cebula 2002; Cebula 1975; Poston Jr., Zhang, Gotcher & Gu 2009; Newbold 1996;
Cullen & Levitt 1999). Most of the literature focuses on utility-maximization as the primary motivator for a person
to move from one place to the next. The assumption behind utility-maximization is the increase in income is the
primary motivation for moving from one place to another. In this case, migration from one state to another would
purely be because of an increase in income which would come from the move which would increase the utility of
that person which would translate into more happiness. In this regard, happiness is based on improved job prospects
and wage-earning potential.
The economic assumptions behind internal migration have been challenged when considering noneconomic factors related to quality of life. One of the reasons behind this movement could be due to the increasing
homogeneity on economic factors such as income and taxation across the United States. As these economic factors
become more similar across the United States, people may look for other reasons to move from one state to another.
This could also be related to a cultural shift in the United States in which there has been more emphasis on quality of

life factors than economic factors. Most of the quality of life factors considered in the literature are non-policy
related such as the weather. There has been some research on public safety and other policy-related factors on
migration, but nothing comprehensively looking at the effects of subjective wellbeing on internal migration in the
United States.

4
The relationship between subjective wellbeing and internal migration decisions is currently unknown. It is
assumed that individuals aim to improve their general wellbeing and at the same time compare their wellbeing with
others. Further it is assumed that individuals pursue wellbeing to the extent that they are willing to relocate to be in
an area that will maximize their wellbeing. These internal migration decisions could relocate them across town,
across county lines or state lines. This study is a state-level analysis on subjective wellbeing as an incentive for
internal migration decisions. It is assumed that as a state’s wellbeing increases it attracts others who migrate to that
state.
This article combines two literary traditions, the literature on wellbeing and the literature on internal
migration. As previously covered, much of the literature on internal migration attributes migration decision-making
to economic factors such as income and employment and non-economic factors such as quality of life. Wellbeing as
a cause for migration fits relatively well between the economic and non-economic factors as wellbeing is often
measured by income and quality of life indexes. In this article wellbeing is considered a non-economic cause for
migration. This paper is an exploratory study on an under-researched topic in the internal migration and
wellbeing/happiness literature.

The following section is a summary of the literature on the causes of internal migration in the United States
as well as the definition of wellbeing and the potential relationship between migration and wellbeing. The next
section is a description of the design used in this study including how the key variables were measured, the
timeframe, the selected model, diagnostics and methods of interpretation. The section that follows this is the results
section which report on the regression statistics. Lastly, a discussion section is included to discuss the meaning of
these results and the need for further research in this area and a conclusion section summarizes the findings and the
discussion.
Literature Review
The relationship between perceived improvements in wellbeing and migration is considered to be a part of
the American dream. Clausen (2008) notes that, “unless prompted by disaster of one sort or another, moving may be
the most important form the individual pursuit of utopia can take, a brave and insouciant gamble that the future will
be tangibly better than the past” (22). This encompasses the adage that the grass is always greener on the other side.
People migrated to the American colonies for perceived increases in religious freedom and increased opportunities.
People migrated across the western territories for similar reasons.

5
Pierson (1954 / 2011) outlined the mobility of the American people in which it has come to be one of the
defining characteristics of American culture. In his essay he explained the many reasons why Americans move from
one place to another. One of the reasons he cited is because, “movement means improvement” (Pierson 1954 / 2011,
97). Even in the 1950s he pointed out that because the United States has developed into a society where information

flows freely between people informed decisions on the best place for them can be made while people have the
freedom to migrate there.
The free access of information on potential destinations for migrating people is crucial in economic and
non-economic rationales for migration. In the United States today information on potential destinations throughout
the country is readily available in the age of big data. Along with big data many have attempted to condense this
information into readily understood indexes like the Gallup-Healthways Wellbeing Index. Another example is the
Freedom in the 50 States Index which considers overall freedom, not just economic freedom (Ruger & Sorens
2011).
Even if people are not informed by the surge of information available in cyberspace migration theorists
have considered the impact that social ties and networks have had on informing potential migrants. These could be
family, friendship or hometown ties. These could also be symbolic ties between people of a particular ethnicity or
faith. In addition, it may only require the initial migrants to make the informed decision to move there while later
migrants simply follow their lead in a supposed ‘herd effect’ (Boswell 2008; Epstein & Gang 2006; Epstein 2008).
In the literature on happiness there has been a move away from a simple conception of happiness as utilitymaximization to a subjective understanding of happiness which has evolved into a more complex understanding of
happiness which is wellbeing (Bogen & Farrell 1978; Kenny 1999; Frey & Stutzer 2000; Brϋlde 2010; Veenhoven
2000; Easterlin 2003; Eckersley 2009; Helm 2000). It is very likely that this concept has evolved as people have
evolved in their conception of what it means to be happy. Rebhun and Raveh (2006) made this point in which they
stated, “from the moment that a certain standard of living has been attained or, in a more general way as the standard
of living rises, people will often be prepared to exchange purely economic advantages for qualities connected with
comfort” (139). They found that over time (1970 to 1990) preferences shifted from economic concerns to concerns

of comfort or quality of life for those who migrated from one state to another. The authors also found that quality of
life factors correlated strongly with economic factors.

6
The decrease in the prevalence of economic factors could be in response to an increasing homogeneity
between locations on these factors. Rhode and Strumpf (2003) found in their study of the differences in taxation
between cities and counties over a 140 year period ending in 1990 that the level of heterogeneity between them has
decreased substantially. These are differences between cities and counties which are more apt to be different across
the country than between states.
An increase in homogeneity also could have been accompanied by a cultural shift in which shared norms
and beliefs have led potential migrants to consider the information reaching them from the web or from networks
differently either because of that information or because of their own shift in preferences (Boswell 2008). Slowly,
there has been a realization that migration for non-economic reasons is starting to play a larger role such as when
Ruger and Sorens (2011) conclude in their study of the effects of overall freedom and net internal migration, “the
most plausible interpretation is that Americans in general are indeed attracted to freedom for its own sake, not just
for the economic benefits” (18).
This leads to the discussion on how the reported subjective wellbeing of a state’s residents may induce
others to migrate to that state. In the Gallup-Healthways measure there are questions on life satisfaction, emotional
happiness, health and healthy behaviors, and contentment with one’s work and community. In this survey there is a
comprehensive view of happiness/wellbeing that includes both short-term and long-term happiness. This survey is

also primarily focused on non-pecuniary causes of happiness.
Assuming that there has been a cultural shift in defining what makes a person happy and that information is
either received through the web or through different types of networks about the wellbeing of people in different
places, there is an impetus for people to migrate to places where there is a higher wellbeing amongst the people.
The comparison theory of happiness is crucial to this understanding. Veenhoven (2006) characterizes this theory in
that it assumes that people are comparing their life with a subjective view of how their life should be. The idea of
‘keeping with up with the Joneses’ is central to this idea as well as internal goals that the individual or society has
inculcated as important. When information is received about people who are living at a higher level of wellbeing
whether it is having more life satisfaction, better access to community resources, higher levels of health or better
emotional health there is an incentive for those not living there to want to relocate there so they can also potentially
enjoy a better level of wellbeing.

7
The impetus to migrate to a place for any reason does not mean that a person or family will relocate there.
As uncovered in the migration literature there are a large number of reasons for relocating to a place and there are
impediments to migration such as the cost in migrating. Migrants themselves may also be a self-selected group of
people in which any discussion of migration is confined to a discussion of individuals who possess a certain
characteristic that leads them to migrate more than others. Besides these issues, it cannot be ignored that within
migration theory people, whether self-selected or not, will chose a location because it offers an improvement over
the current location. The bulk of this research has rested on economic improvement, but at the core is the belief in

utility-maximization and the accompanying happiness. The beliefs on happiness have shifted widely to nonpecuniary causes so has the beliefs on the causes of migration. It is not a leap within this framework to propose that
people will choose to migrate to a place that will maximize their wellbeing. The Gallup-Healthways indicators on
wellbeing simply report on what many may be aware of through their information networks. The life in a particular
state may be perceived as good. Possibly it was a tv show, a friend who visited or is living there, a story in the news,
or the Gallup measure itself that motivated people to relocate there.
One study by Nowok, van Ham, Findlay and Gayle (2013) asked if migration brings higher levels of
subjective wellbeing. The authors note that, “from a theoretical perspective, incorporating subjective wellbeing in
an explanation of migration decision-making can still be encompassed within a utility-maximizing framework”
(Nowok et.al. 2013, 987). They assumed that by migrating there is a perceived increase in quality of life and
happiness. The authors looked at before and after migration subjective wellbeing scores to determine if there were
any substantial increases in actual subjective wellbeing from the move across communities in the United Kingdom.
Nowok et.al. (2013) found that migrants were actually less happy than non-migrants in which their
unhappiness increased the more times they migrated. They found that the happiest migrants were those aged 23 to
40 and added that, “the higher subjective wellbeing of migrants at the most mobile ages, which drives the happiness
of the whole population, suggest a positive impact of changing place of residence, at least in the short term” (Nowok
et.al. 2013, 993). Further, the authors found that job related moves lead to happier people while the longer the
distance the happier the people also. It also appears that migration plans tend to boost happiness prior to the move,
but after the move it stagnates.
Nowok et.al. (2013) were concerned with subjective wellbeing after migration. This article is concerned
about subjective wellbeing as a primer for migration decisions to a destination with a higher general subjective


8
wellbeing score amongst its residents. It is assumed that a state with a higher subjective wellbeing amongst its
residents will attract others who are seeking to maximize their wellbeing. The comparison theory of happiness
applies the most to this study. The comparison theory applies because residents in one state with a lower subjective
wellbeing will compare themselves with other residents in other states who have a higher subjective wellbeing.
Those with higher wellbeing will represent how life should be and create incentives for those outside that state to
relocate there. As noted by Nowok et.al. (2013), the very idea of relocating increases the happiness of the migrants
even before migration. It is assumed that this happiness increases substantially when considering relocation to a
state with a higher wellbeing. Further it is assumed that people wish to capitalize on this happiness by relocating to
these places.
States have an incentive to increase net in-migration because of the relationship between population and
economic development and state government fiscal stability. A miserable state will only increase out-migration and
deter in-migration. It is no coincidence that the State of West Virginia, for example, has one of the largest levels of
out-migration and at the same time has the lowest scores on the Gallup-Healthways Wellbeing Index. Many of the
cities in West Virginia are shrinking cities and not coincidently they are also fiscally-stressed. The relationship
between population and governmental fiscal health has been established in the literature for a long time (Bradbury,
Downs & Small 1982; Henderick 2004). In addition population loss has been associated with increases in crime,
declines in housing values, decreases in quality of life and increases in public service costs (Harries 2004; Schilling
& Logan 2008; Rousseau 2009; Hollander 2010; Accordino & Johnson 2000; Winthrop & Herr 2009; Moss 2008).

In this case states and their local governments have an incentive to retain the population that they have while
attracting new people. It is not assumed that improving wellbeing will be the only thing that states need to do, but it
should be part of their approach besides the obvious moral reasons to do so.
Study Design
Surveys have attempted to capture some measurable level of subjective wellbeing. They are either single
item questionnaires such as the Cantril Ladder or the single question on happiness in the United States’ General
Social Survey or they are multi-item questionnaires such as the Oxford Happiness Inventory or the Subjective
Happiness Scale. The multi-item questionnaires are better tools at capturing subjective wellbeing (Helm 2000). At
this stage in the development of wellbeing/happiness measurements the discrete rating scale is widely accepted with
some efforts at creating a continuous measure (Studer 2012).

9
The discrete rating scale is one of the weaknesses of the subjective wellbeing measure. There are also
problems with different measures of happiness having differing effects on outcomes depending on the definition
used (Borooah 2005). There are also cultural differences when answering the subjective wellbeing questions which
could hurt the validity of the instrument. There are also concerns over whether the questions asked are
comprehensive enough to capture wellbeing.
The Gallup-Healthways Wellbeing Index is one such index that attempts to be as comprehensive as possible
incorporating multiple questions to capture both positive affect and life satisfaction. The index is based on
telephone interviews of at least 1000 random adult respondents across the fifty states and different congressional
districts on a daily basis. It is one large index composed of six smaller indexes, life evaluation, emotional health,
physical health, healthy behavior, work environment and basic access. Due to the comprehensiveness of the index it
is the most descriptive of subjective wellbeing and it is used as the explanatory variable of interest in this study
(Gallup-Healthways 2009).
There are different ways to measure in-migration, but most studies use net in-migration. Ruger and Sorens
(2011) used net internal migration by state for the years 2000 to 2009 over the population in 2000 for their study on
the effects of total freedom on in-migration. Treyz et.al. (1993) used net economic migration which removes noneconomic migrants from their study of the expected wage on in-migration. Cebula (1975) used net migration in
which he simply subtracted out-migrants from in-migrants in his study of quality of life influences on net migration.
Conway and Houtenville (2003) used net inflows which is the same as net in-migration in their study of age groups
and migration. They also used gross migration flows as well. Johnson, Voss, Hammer, Fuguitt and McNiven (2005)
used expected births / deaths and compared this with the Census data for that year in which they divided the actual
population by the expected population in their study of the patterns of migration based on age, spatial and functional
characteristics. Poston Jr. et.al. (2009) measured in-migration as in-migration for a certain period minus outmigration during the same period as a percentage of state population in the beginning of this period for their study of
the effects of climate on net in-migration.
The net in-migration score used by Poston Jr. et.al. (2009) is used in this study. The reason that this
measure was selected is because it appears to be similar to other measures used by other studies in which inmigration is weighted by out-migration and the previous period total population. In addition, Poston Jr. et.al. (2009)

10
used this measure in a state-level, cross-sectional multiple regression which is the design of this study. This variable
serves as the outcome variable in this study.
One research question is of primary importance in this article. Does the reported subjective wellbeing of a
state attract more in-migrants as measured by net in-migration? It is hypothesized that as a state’s subjective
wellbeing score increases so does the level of in-migration to that state. This hypothesis is rooted in the migration
literature in which the quality of life influenced by the natural environment or state-level policy decisions has a
positive effect on in-migration to those states that capitalize on these wellbeing indicators. This paper does not
distinguish between natural or human-induced quality of life factors however there is an assumption that policy
decisions do have a large influence on these factors. It is further assumed in this paper as discussed in the literature
that the impetus to relocate to a state because of perceived improvements to personal wellbeing is based on the free
flow of information and social networks in which people are able to compare their own wellbeing in the current state
with those in another state. This is based on the comparison theory of happiness discussed in the literature.
The average subjective wellbeing scores from the Gallup-Healthways Wellbeing Index for a state between
the years 2008 and 2010 are used in this study (Gallup 2010). The survey started in 2008 and in-migration data for
2010 are used here. The net in-migration measure used by Poston Jr. et.al. (2009) is used in this study. In-migration
from 2005 to 2010 is subtracted by out-migration for the same period and divided by the state population in 2005.
State migration data are available through the Census (United States Census 2010; United States Census 2005). Inmigration serves as the dependent variable and wellbeing as the independent variable.
The number of states used in this analysis is 48, not including Alaska and Hawaii. Poston Jr. et.al. (2009)
and Cebula (1975) excluded these states because of their unique location vis-à-vis other states. Migrating from
Hawaii and Alaska has unique challenges that migrating from Pennsylvania or any other contiguous state does not
have when moving to another state. Due to these unique challenges the states were excluded from this analysis.
A cross-sectional, multiple regression was used with the data. Significance was determined at the .10
probability level. This type of model provides a snapshot in time although the dependent variable and the
independent variable are calculated over several years which smooth the variances created by time. Some of the
control variables are lagged and others are measured at the maximum year of the study based on the potential
influences these variables may have on the dependent variable. The snapshot that this model provides is a first step
as research matures on this subject. In addition, a cross-sectional multiple regression model using states as the unit

11
of analysis is ubiquitous in the migration literature. As discussed in the literature review, Cebula and Nair-Reichert
(2012), Poston Jr. et.al. (2009), Ruger and Sorens (2011) and Ashby (2007) cited in this paper, for example, all
approached the subject of in-migration utilizing this same methodology. The relationship between perceptions of
improvements to personal wellbeing by migrating to another state that is perceived as a state that maximizes
wellbeing within its borders would require either a panel or time-series model with assumptions of non-linearity for
more confidence in these results. Theoretically, the relationship between state-level wellbeing and net in-migration
explored in this paper may be linear in the short term, but curved in the long term. This is explored in more detail in
the discussion section.
The issue of spatial correlation was also tested on the dependent variable to determine the correct model
since a cross-sectional study would potentially bias results from unobserved economic and policy conditions. A
Lagrange Multiplier and Robust Lagrange Multiplier were calculated for spatial lag and spatial error using the opensource software Geoda™. The LM test is considered a more optimal test of spatial lags and errors. It was found
that none of the values were significant at the .10 level for any of the tests for either the spatial lag or spatial error
model indicating that there were no problems with spatial correlation in the data necessitating a maximum likelihood
or instrumental variables estimator (Kalenkoski & Lacombe 2008; Gibson, Kim & Olivia 2011). The results of
these tests can be found in table 1.
A number of control variables were introduced based on the migration literature. State-level
unemployment rate, housing price index score, income per capita, violent crimes per state, the number of 18 to 44
year olds per state (thousands), the number of 65+ year olds per state (thousands), percent of state population with a
college degree, percent of state population that is African American/White/Latino/Asian, and the amount of
spending per state (billions) were used as controls. Data for the demographic, spending, housing price, college
attainment and age variables are from the U.S. Census. Data on unemployment are from Bureau of Labor Statistics
and per capita income data are from the U.S. Department of Commerce. Violent crime data are from the Federal
Bureau of Investigations.
All of the control variables were measured in 2010 except the race variables which were measured in 2005.
The racial composition of a state at the beginning of the migration period could indicate a migration stream for that
particular racial group. In addition, past migration streams were also controlled for by averaging net in-migration to
a state from 1940 to 2000 which would represent the period before the migration period considered in this paper.

12
The descriptive statistics for the control variables and the dependent and independent variables can be found in
tables 2 and 3.
The net in-migration ranged from -5.75 percent of 2005 population levels to 7.18 percent of 2005
population levels. The average wellbeing score ranged from 61.60 to 68.83 indicating a lower level of variation on
the wellbeing score than the in-migration / out-migration percent. The lower the wellbeing score the lower the
wellbeing in that state.
Some of the control variables also displayed non-normal characteristics necessitating transformation.
Income per capita, spending per state, number of 18 to 44 year olds, percent college attainment, percent Latino,
percent Asian and violent crimes per state were logged due to normality issues. The percent African American was
taken at the square root also due to normality issues. In addition, most of the control variables were highly
correlated creating a problem with multicollinearity. Instead of removing some of these variables from the analysis
new variables were created through a principal components analysis. The purpose of this analysis is to take
collinear variables and, “reduce them to a subset of uncorrelated factors” (Field 2013, p. 674).
The variables that were included in the principal components analysis are log of spending by state, log of
violent crimes, log of the number of 18 to 44 year olds (thousands), the number of 65+ year olds (thousands), log per
capita income, log percent college attainment, square root of percent African American, log percent Latino, log
percent Asian, percent White, unemployment and the housing price index. These 12 variables factored into two
components. The first component can be labeled demographics, spending and unemployment. The variables that
loaded into this component are log of spending by state, log of violent crimes, log of the number of 18 to 44 year
olds, the number of 65+ year olds, square root of percent African American, percent White, log percent Latino, log
percent Asian and unemployment. All of them loaded positively into this component except percent White per state.
The second component can be labeled income, education and housing. The variables that loaded into this
component are log per capita income, log of percent college attainment and the housing price index. All these
variables had positive relationships. These two components serve as new variables in the multiple regression. Table
4 has the individual scores of each variable on each component.
The Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin measure was used to determine if the sampling was adequate for the principal
components analysis in which the KMO score was .745 indicating that it was adequate. The anti-image matrix also
revealed that each variable had an adequate sample size for the analysis. The reproduced correlation found that 62%

13
of the non-redundant residuals were above .05 which indicates that there may be a problem with model fit (Field,
2013).
In summary, the variables used in the multiple regression on net in-migration as a percent of 2005
population levels (In-Migration) are the average wellbeing score per state (Wellbeing), the income, education and
housing factor (Factor 1), the demographics, spending and unemployment factor (Factor 2) and average net
migration (Migration). The model with these variables is represented in mathematical form below. The notation s
represents each individual state.
In-Migrations = α0 + β1 (Wellbeing)s + β2 (Factor 1)s + β3 (Factor 2)s + β4 (Migration)s + εs
Results
The statistical program SPSS v. 22 was used to calculate the results of the model. This program produces
various statistics in which the standardized and unstandardized betas (b) are the primary focus of the results. The
unstandardized betas are the raw effects on the dependent variable by increasing the independent variable by one
unit while holding the other variables constant. The standardized betas (β) are the effects in standard deviations on
the outcome variable by a one standard deviation change in the predictor while holding the other predictors constant.
The standardized betas are more comparable to each other than the unstandardized betas.
The wellbeing score used in this analysis is significantly and positively related to net in-migration at the .10
probability level. The unstandardized beta in table 5 shows that as the wellbeing score increases by one the net inmigration increases by .71 percent of 2005 population totals for that state. This indicates that as a state’s wellbeing
score improves the level of net in-migration increases for that state.
Only one of the two factors is significantly related to net in-migration. The factored variable
demographics, spending and unemployment (Factor 2) is significant at the .01 level and negatively related to net inmigration. Past migration streams represented by the average net migration to a state was also significant at the .10
level and positively related to net in-migration. In both of these cases the direction of influence on the outcome
variable was expected based on the literature.
The standardized betas provide a clearer picture on the potential impact of these variables on the dependent
variable for the purposes of comparison. The demographics, spending and unemployment factor had the largest
impact amongst the variables and it was also the most significant. Wellbeing was a little more than half of this

14
impact on the dependent variable while being less significant. Average net migration was slightly lower in its
impact on the dependent variable and also significant at the same level as wellbeing.
Discussion
As discussed in the literature review of this paper, there is a limited focus on the effects of subjective
wellbeing on migration. Nowok et.al. (2013) explained that subject wellbeing can be a catalyst for moving and the
desire to improve it. Their research was on the post-migration effects on wellbeing and mostly assumed that those
that moved sought to improve their wellbeing. The research in this paper sought to explore whether that was truly a
catalyst for moving using the comparison theory of happiness as the basis for that assumption. Rebhun and Raveh
(2006) on the other hand were more clearly interested in the reasons for moving from one place to another and found
that quality of life factors like inequality, education, medical care and crime (objective measures of wellbeing) were
a catalyst for migration into or out of a place.
This study is unique by approaching wellbeing utilizing a subjective wellbeing score. The migration
literature has included objective aspects of wellbeing / quality of life as a cause of in-migration / out-migration for
some time and the results of these studies are in line with the results of this study. Some of these factors
representing the quality of life in a place have focused on the environment such as temperature and climate. Some
of these factors have also focused on the effects of government policy. A good portion of this research has used
states as the unit of analysis.
These analyses have attempted to define objective wellbeing / quality of life through one of two
orientations, negative or positive rights. Negative rights are those limits placed on government i.e. more freedom for
those in the state. Positive rights are those obligations placed on government i.e. more services for those in the state
(Usman 2010). In the literature, Ruger and Sorens (2011) found that a decrease in fiscal, regulatory and paternalism
burdens from the state leads to more in-migration to that state. These authors focused on both economic and
personal freedom while most of the literature in this sphere has focused only on economic freedom. In contrast, a
number of studies have found that more government expenditures and services leads to more in-migration such as
through the development of parks, public safety and sanitation, welfare and road expenditures (Cebula 2005; Ashby
2007; Cebula 2002; Huang, Orazem & Wohlgemuth 2002).
In both of these cases where the objective measures of wellbeing confirmed their potential influences on
fueling in-migration / out-migration this study confirmed with a subjective measure. People who are subjectively

15
happy or unhappy may be because of less services or less freedom but these surveys on subjective wellbeing
confirm whether the people are actually happy or unhappy. This study is one potential confirmation that this matters
when people are choosing to migrate to another state.
The significance of the average wellbeing score with state net in-migration is an important finding in this
article with important implications for public policy. The Gallup-Healthways Wellbeing Index captures life
evaluations by classifying respondents as thriving, struggling and suffering on the Cantril Ladder Scale. A state with
a relatively large number of residents struggling or suffering is a cause for concern for the policymakers in that state
and creates disincentives in relocating there. According to Gallup, only 45% of Americans responded that they are
thriving with the majority either struggling or suffering. Gallup compares this percentage with Denmark where 82%
of respondents on the same scale felt they were thriving (Gallup-Healthways, 2009).
Overall, those states in the top ten of wellbeing are attracting more migrants than those in the bottom ten of
wellbeing. States such as Utah, Wyoming, Montana and Minnesota have the highest average wellbeing scores
amongst the lower 48 states. States such as West Virginia, Kentucky, Mississippi and Arkansas have the lowest
average wellbeing scores amongst the lower 48 states.
This study set out to determine if state wellbeing had a significant relationship with state net in-migration.
A significant and positive relationship was found between these variables. The relationship indicates that state
wellbeing could be a positive incentive for in-migration to that state or a negative incentive for out-migration from
that state. States should invest time and resources to covering those areas that improve their resident’s wellbeing
both to retain those residents as well as attract new residents.
The larger question that is not necessarily answered in this paper is whether the government has an impact
on the happiness / wellbeing of their constituents. A positive answer to this question only leads to another question
on what those governments can do to maximize general wellbeing in the state. Wassmer, Lascher Jr. and Kroll
(2009) found that individual happiness is related to government activity per person through public safety
expenditures. Ng and Ho (2006) contend that unhappiness is caused by a loss of freedoms however people want law
and order and assistance during bad times. In contrast, Ackerson & Subramanian (2010) found that states with more
negative rights (more freedom) i.e. less constraints by government also have a high unintentional injury mortality
rate. The results in this small sample of the literature seem to indicate that government policy has an impact on the
happiness / wellbeing of the citizenry, but there is no definitive approach to how to maximize that wellbeing. There

16
is definitely an optimal level of personal freedom, state intervention and state spending that can be achieved
however this might be subject to shifting circumstances and ideologies.
The constantly shifting expectations by the residents towards government may require governments
whether at the state or local level to create an open feedback loop that involves active citizen engagement and
involvement so that it is known what is needed, how much of it is needed, where the government should get
involved and where it should stand down. Optimally these decisions would be best under unanimous decisionmaking which could only be achieved through active deliberation and compromise. This might be very challenging
at the state-level so less than optimal solutions like a state-wide poll of a selected representative sample could be
done where lines of confluence determine those policy initiatives that best impact the wellbeing of its constituents.
In addition, there may be certain areas that are consistently associated with wellbeing that span ideology
and context that researchers will have to continue to work on understanding to provide policymakers with
empirically-verified directions for policy development and implementation. At the very least, the research in this
paper provides some proof that it may actually matter for people living in a state whether they are subjectively
happy or not and that states should be concerned about this especially as other states may be making their residents
happier than others. As stated previously, this matters in a federal system of public finance where states rely on a
substantial proportion of their revenues from own-sources derived from people living in the state. Of course, it also
matters who is moving into and out of these states. The poor tend to be less mobile than the rich especially for
greater distances such as that required for inter-state movement, but this is not a call for states to focus on attracting
the well-off at the expense of the poor. In any case, any neglect of the poor by the state may also have an impact on
crime which has an impact on general wellbeing.
There were some weaknesses with this study. A panel study would best capture the effects of wellbeing on
net in-migration over time. The cross-sectional design employed here only differentiates between the limited
number of cases (48) which may or may not capture the full or true effect of state wellbeing on net in-migration.
Unfortunately, the data used for this study does not allow this type of analysis. Additionally, this is a macro-study of
migration decision-making. A more thorough analysis would survey the actual migrants to determine their
incentives. It would also be helpful to survey those that choose to remain in the state as well. This would also help
limit any selection bias by focusing only on migrants.

17
Future studies could use the newly developed wellbeing measures for metropolitan statistical areas that
would lower the level of analysis which would increase the variability and population size of the units of analysis.
In addition, states that migrants are leaving and entering could be compared to each other to determine if those
migrants are leaving states that are lower in wellbeing than those states that they are entering. At the macro-level
this is being done in this study, but this approach would provide further detail.
The problems of endogeneity need to be thoroughly investigated in future studies which Nowok et.al.
(2013) attempt to do in their study of whether migrating increases wellbeing or wellbeing increases the likelihood of
migrating. In addition, it may be important to separate economic migrants from non-economic migrants if the data
will allow this. Non-economic migrants would be the main interest in any study of the effects of wellbeing and
migration.
Lastly, the inhibiting effects related to migration need to be considered in a study of wellbeing and
migration. It may be that many would like to leave a state where they are suffering, but are unable because of fiscal
constraints. There is a general belief in the migration literature that as people become better off these effects may
have less of an effect over time which would limit the selectivity of migrants making the results of these studies
much more generalizable. Rebhun and Raveh (2006) stated that, “as migration becomes less selective, it will
probably involve a wider range of causations within the different social, economic, cultural, environmental and
psychological arenas” (155). One of those psychological arenas will be wellbeing. Rhode and Strumpf (2003)
found that mobility costs have decreased over the 140 year period of their study and it is suspected that these costs
will continue to decrease over time.
Conclusion
The relationship between the subjective wellbeing in a state and net in-migration to that state was studied in
this paper. The results indicate that the subjective wellbeing in a state may have a significant positive influence on
net in-migration. These results accord with the general migration literature that focuses on quality of life factors as a
determiner of in-migration / out-migration.
It is assumed in this paper and in the general migration and wellbeing literature that government policy has
an influence on wellbeing and that it should strive to maximize the general wellbeing. The findings in this paper
help to emphasize that people are willing to ‘vote with their feet’ within the Tiebout sorting mode and relocate not

18
only across county-lines, but across state-lines to maximize their wellbeing. It is recommended in this paper that
state policymakers consider the impacts of policy on subjective wellbeing.
The weaknesses of this study are based on the statistical model selected which is related to the constraints
of the data. It is recommended as data becomes more available that more sophisticated statistical methods be
applied to fully understand the relationship between state and local general subjective wellbeing on in-migration /
out-migration to those places. It is also recommended that Gallup-Healthways include a question in the survey on
how important the maximization to wellbeing was to making a decision to remain in the state or city or migrate to
another place. In addition, it would also be important to include another question in that survey to assess the
knowledge that the respondent had regarding the general wellbeing in their place of migration before they migrated
there. This would help to overcome some of the unknowns regarding these types of migration decisions.
References
Accordino, J., & Johnson, G. T. (2000). Addressing the vacant and abandoned property problem. Journal of Urban
Affairs, 22(3), 301 - 315.
Ackerson, L. K., & Subramanian, S. V. (2010). Negative Freedom and Death in the United States. American Journal
of Public Health, 100(11), 2163-2164.
Ashby, N. J. (2007). Economic freedom and migration flows between U.S.

Dokumen yang terkait

Konflik Internal dalam Komunitas Gay (Studi Etnografi pada Komunitas IGAMA)

2 28 65

Determinasi Penyaluran Kredit Pemilikan Rumah (KPR) Bank Persero di Indonesia Periode 2008.1-2015.11: Pendekatan Error Correction Model (Determination Mortgage Lending (KPR) Distribution State Banks In Indonesia Period 2008.1-2015.11: Error Correction Mod

1 21 9

Evaluasi Pengendalian Internal Dalam Menunjang Efektivitas Sistem Pemberian Kredit Usaha Mikro Kecil Menengah (Studi Kasus Bank UMKM Cabang Jember); Evaluation Of Internal Control To Effectiveness Credit System Umkm (A Case Study of Bank UMKM Jember Branc

0 17 8

Evaluasi Pengendalian Internal Pembiayaan Murabahah Pada BMT Sidogiri

1 20 9

Pengaruh Kualitas Audit, Kondisi Keuangan Perusahaan, Dan Auditor Internal Terhadap Opini Audit Going Concern : Studi Empiris Pada Perbankan Yabg Terdaftar Di Bursa Efek Indonesia

2 30 70

Aripin, “Existentialism of Jack in David Fincher‟s Fight Club Film”. A Thesis. Adab and Humanities Faculty, English Letters Department, Syarif Hidayatullah State Islamic University. Jakarta 2014. This research focused on the main character in Fight Club f

0 19 38

Prosedur Verifikasi Internal Surat Pertanggung Jawaban (SPJ) Pada Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Daerah Provinsi Jawa Barat

2 110 1

Membuat Modul Manajemen Diskusi Antar Pegawai pada Aplikasi Internal di Diskominfo (Dinas Komunikasi dan Informatika) Provinsi Jawa Barat

0 29 140

Audit Pengendalian Internal Terhadap Fungsi Penjualan E-Ticketing Dengan Menggunakan Kerangka Kerja Cobit 4.1 Pada Travel Bimo Trans Cabang Dipatiukur Bandung

0 13 1

Analisis Kemampuan Profesional Dan Independensi Auditor Internal Terhadap Kualitas Laporan Audit Pada PT. Pindad (Persero)

0 13 1