The flat-rate tariff Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Energy Economics:Vol22.Issue4.2000:

M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463]495 478 Ž . The cumulative distribution function H x describes the percent of the popula- t tion that spends x or less of their income on electricity consumption. The equity Ž . measure E E t , f is defined in terms of this quantity: 2 x Ž . Ž . Ž . E E t , f s H x s h y d y, H 2 t t and is a function 7 of the evaluation parameter x. This is a more accurate and comprehensive assessment of equity as compared to the moment method. Tariff t 1 Ž . Ž . is thus preferred to tariff t and is said to be more equitable if E E t , f E E t , f ; 2 2 1 2 2 Ž . Ž . i.e. H 0.1 H 0.1 . t t 1 2

4. The flat-rate tariff

A flat tariff rate is a one]parameter tariff that provides a benchmark for comparison with more complicated tariff designs. A flat tariff rate is the simplest possible tariff and is still the most widely used throughout the world, especially for residential rates. A flat tariff is given by Ž . t s t ADRrkWh , 1 or in other words, a flat rate of t is imposed for any quantity of electricity 1 consumed. This neither encourages nor discourages consumption. A consumer who Ž . uses E kWh electricity per month is charged t E ADR . The total revenue i 1 i Ž . R R t , f generated by the tariff is thus given by: Ž . R R t , f s Ýt E s t ÝE s t E 1 i 1 i 1 T , where E represents the total electricity consumption of the sample S S . It is clear T that under a flat-rate tariff, total revenue does not depend explicitly on the shape of the distribution curve, but only on the total amount of consumption in the sample. A plot of revenue vs. quantity electricity consumed for a typical residential consumer is a linear function that passes through the origin with slope t . 1 A number of conclusions result from the application of the flat-rate tariff. The first two results hold in general and follow from the revenue expression. Ž . 1. R R t ,f is an increasing linear function of t and is independent of the form of f . Ž . 2. The average value E g is an increasing linear function of t. For a given sample S S , E is fixed and revenue is a linear function of t, and so T 7 The choice of the value x s 10 is arbitrary but appeared to be a natural cut-off when examining Ž . the output data of the analysis although in principle any value can be used . In fact, due to the Ž . Ž . complicated nature of the functional and its dependence on the underlying distribution h x , H x t t may induce ambiguous preferences as the cut-off value x changes. M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463]495 479 Table 5 Flat tariff rate and related parameters Ž . Ž . Ž . Tariff t R R t , f E g H 0.10 t Ž . Ž . ADRrkWh ADR 10 596 957 5.4 91.7 12 756 349 6.5 87.2 14 855 741 7.6 80.5 16 955 132 8.7 70.3 18 1 074 524 9.7 64.2 20 1 193 915 10.8 58.1 22 1 313 307 11.9 50.6 24 1 432 693 13.0 40.7 Ž . as the magnitude of the flat-rate increases decreases , the revenue generated Ž . will increase decrease in proportion to the tariff. In the short-run, therefore, and assuming no change in the consumer response, total revenues will vary linearly with the tariff change. In the long-run, however, as individuals adjust their consumption patterns in accord with the new tariff, the revenue change is dependent on the price elasticity of demand of the population. In the short-run, the percentage of a household’s income spent on electricity Ž . Ž . will rise fall with a tariff increase decrease . This can be seen as follows. The random variable g s C r I is described by the density function h, and in the discrete case, the expected value of g is given by: Ž . Ž . Ž . Ýg Ý C rI Ý E t rI t Ý E rI i i i i 1 i 1 i i g s s s s , n n n n a linear function of t since E and I are fixed in the sample data. i i The next two conclusions are empirical results based on the specific form of the Ž . collected data refer to Table 5 : 3. The percentage of the population that spends 10 or less of their total income Ž Ž .. Ž . on electricity consumption H 0.1 is a decreasing approximately linear t function of t. Ž . Ž . Ž . 4. Total revenue R R t , f and H 0.1 are approximately negatively correlated. t Ž . Ž . Ž . As total revenue increases, the equity E E t , f s E E t , f as measured by H 0.10 , 2 t decreases. From Fig. 4 it is clear that the equity measure is an approximately linear . decreasing function of t. Since revenue R R t ,f and t are proportional, this is Ž . equivalent to stating that total revenue is approximately a linear decreasing Ž . Ž . function of H 0.10 as shown in Fig. 5. A plot of revenue R R t ,f vs. equity E E t , f t represents an ‘efficient frontier’; i.e. it is not possible to increase revenue without a subsequent decrease in equity, and vice-versa. Note that the shape of the efficient Ž . frontier depends on the specific value of x used in H x . t M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 480 Ž . Fig. 4. Graph of the equity measure E E t , f as a function of the tariff rate t for a flat-rate tariff. M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 481 Ž . Ž . Fig. 5. Graph of the total revenue R R t ,f vs. the equity measure E E t ,f . M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463]495 482

5. The two-tier tariff