The two-tier tariff Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Energy Economics:Vol22.Issue4.2000:

M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463]495 482

5. The two-tier tariff

A general model for the two-tier tariff rate is given as: Ž . Ž . t ADRrkWh if E F E kWh 1 i t s ½ Ž . Ž . t ADRrkWh if E E kWh . 2 i Ž . For the first E kWh electricity consumed per month, the price is t ADRrkWh , 1 Ž . and for the balance of the monthly consumption E y E , the price is i Ž . t ADRrkWh . This is a form of lifeline pricing which involves charging a low, 2 subsidized price for a fixed energy quota and a higher price for consumption above that level. A plot of revenue vs. quantity electricity consumed is a piecewise linear function that changes slope from t to t at the value given by E . The tariff t can 1 2 Ž be represented by the parameters t , t and E written in vector form as t s t , 1 2 1 . t , E , and so the two-tier rate structure is a three-parameter tariff design; e.g. in 2 Ž . Armenia from January 1997 to September 1997, t s 13, 20, 100 . Similar to the flat-rate analysis, a class of tariff rates dependent upon the parameters t , t and E can be compared, and an optimal tariff in terms of 1 2 revenue and equity can be determined. The major distinction between the flat-rate and the two-tier rate is that the tariff is no longer a function of a single variable; tariff design is a function of three parameters and by design gives more flexibility in terms of distributional impact. 5.1. Parametric analysis An approximate range for the tariff parameters was a priori assigned and based on the nominal settings, t s 13, t s 20, E s 100: 1 2 4 t :s 10, 13, 16 1 4 t :s 17, 20, 23 2 4 E :s 75, 100, 125 3 Ž . Associated with each of the 3 s 27 possible tariff combinations 10, 17, 75 , Ž . Ž . Ž . 4 Ž . 10, 17, 100 , 10, 17, 125 , 13, 17, 75 , . . . is a value for the revenue R R t , f and Ž . equity E E s H 0.1 based on the collected sample data. For each tariff rate t Ž . Ž Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž .. combination t, the revenue R R t ,f , moment vector E g , s g , sk g , ku g , and Ž . equity measure H 0.1 is computed directly from the sample data and is summa- t rized in Table 6. An example illustrates a typical computation. Ž .4 The population sample provides energy consumption and income data E , I , i i Ž . and for a given tariff, t s t , t , E is used to compute the cost of consumption 1 2 C and g s C rI . i i i i The values of C and g are functions of t, and the density function of g, h , is t used to determine the equity measure: M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 483 Table 6 Two]tier tariff rates and related parameters Ž . Ž . Tariff t R t , f Moment vector H 0.10 Histogram h t t Ž . Ž . Ž Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž .. t t E ADR E g , s g , sk g , ku g 1, 2, Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . 0, 0.05 0.05, 0.10 0.10, 0.15 0.15, 1 Ž . Ž . 10, 17, 75 911 302 7.2, 4.9, 2.1, 5.9 30 58 7 5 87 Ž . Ž . 10, 17, 100 878 825 6.8, 4.5, 2.2, 7.2 33 55 5 7 89 Ž . Ž . 10, 17, 125 660 020 4.7, 3.4, 3.4, 21.5 67 27 5 1 94 Ž . Ž . 10, 20, 75 1 046 022 8.0, 5.4, 2.0, 4.9 28 54 9 9 82 Ž . Ž . 10, 20, 100 999 625 7.4, 4.9, 2.1, 5.8 28 58 5 9 86 Ž . Ž . 10, 20, 125 956 240 7.0, 4.5, 2.1, 6.9 32 57 5 6 89 Ž . Ž . 10, 23,75 1 180 741 8.7, 5.9, 1.9,4.2 24 52 7 7 76 Ž . Ž . 10, 23, 100 1 120 425 8.0, 5.2, 2.0, 5.0 23 57 8 12 80 Ž . Ž . 10, 23, 123 1 064 024 7.5, 4.7,2.0,5.9 27 58 5 10 85 Ž . Ž . 13, 17, 75 955 671 8.1, 5.5, 2.4, 8.8 27 51 12 10 78 Ž . Ž . 13, 17, 100 937 112 7.8, 5.3, 2.5, 9.8 27 51 10 12 78 Ž . Ž . 13, 17, 125 919 758 7.7, 5.2, 2.6, 10.7 26 51 8 15 77 Ž . Ž . 13, 20, 75 1 090 390 8.8, 6.0, 2.2, 6.9 21 50 20 9 71 Ž . Ž . 13, 20, 100 1 057 912 8.5, 5.6, 2.3, 8.1 21 50 19 11 71 Ž . Ž . 13, 20, 125 1 027 542 8.1, 5.4, 2.4, 5.2 26 52 12 10 78 Ž . Ž . 13, 23, 75 1 225 109 9.6, 6.5, 2.1, 5.6 20 43 27 10 63 Ž . Ž . 13, 23, 100 1 178 712 9.1, 6, 2.2, 6.7 20 50 20 10 70 Ž . Ž . 13, 23, 125 1 135 327 8.6, 5.6, 2.3, 7.9 20 51 16 13 71 Ž . Ž . 16, 17, 75 1 000 039 8.9, 6.3, 2.7, 11.8 24 50 16 10 74 Ž . Ž . 16, 17, 100 995 399 8.9, 6.2, 2.7, 12.2 22 50 17 11 72 Ž . Ž . 16, 17, 125 991 060 8.8, 6.2, 2.7, 12.4 22 50 18 10 72 Ž . Ž . 16, 20, 75 1 134 758 9.7, 6.7, 2.5, 9.4 18 44 26 12 62 Ž . Ž . 16, 20, 100 1 116 199 9.5, 6.5, 2.5, 10.3 19 48 23 10 67 Ž . Ž . 16, 20, 125 1 098 845 9.3, 6.3,2.6,11.1 20 50 20 10 70 Ž . Ž . 16, 23, 75 1 269 477 10.5, 7.1, 2.3, 7.6 15 41 29 15 56 Ž . Ž . 16, 23, 100 1 236 999 10.1, 6.8, 2.4, 8.8 19 44 27 10 63 Ž . Ž . 16, 23, 125 1 206 630 9.8, 6.5, 2.5, 9.8 18 45 27 10 63 M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 484 Ž . Ž . Fig. 6. The histogram h g for the tariff rate t s 10, 17, 75 . t M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 485 Ž . Ž . Fig. 7. The histogram h g for the tariff rate t s 10, 17, 100 . t M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 486 Ž . Ž . Fig. 8. The histogram h g for the tariff rate t s 10, 17, 125 . t M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463]495 487 0.1 Ž . Ž . Ž . E E t , f s H 0.1 s h y d y. H t t Ž . For the tariff t s 10, 17, 75 , the revenue is calculated from the consumption Ž . sample data and yields R R t ,f s 911302 ADR and distribution h as shown in Fig. t 6. The histogram subsequently yields the moment vector: Ž Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž .. Ž . E g , s g , sk g , ku g s 7.2, 4.9, 2.1, 5.9 , Ž . Ž . and H 0.1 s 0.32 q 0.55 s 0.87. For the tariff t s 10, 17, 100 , the revenue t Ž . generated is R R t ,f s 878825 ADR, and the distribution h is shown in Fig 7. The t moment vector of the distribution yields Ž . 6.8, 4.5, 2.2, 7.2 , Ž . and H 0.1 s 0.34 q 0.55 s 0.89. Observe that as revenue declines equity in- t creases, while the average amount of income spent on electricity consumption decreases. The value of g changes in response to the change D E s 100 y 75 s 25 kW, and the amount of change depends upon the form of f and the magnitude of Ž . D E . The distribution h for the tariff t s 10, 17, 125 is depicted in Fig. 8. t 5.2. Model analysis The main results of the non-linear tariff are summarized as follows: Ž . Ž . 1. Total revenue R R t ,f is an increasing function of E g . Ž . 2. Total revenue R R t , f decreases approximately linearly as a function of one Ž . parameter e.g. t , t , or E while holding the other two parameters fixed . 1 2 In terms of the sample data specific to this study: Ž . Ž . 3. The efficient frontier of the R R t , f ]E E t , f graph is composed of the Pareto- Ž . U optimal efficient or non-dominated tariffs t : U Ž . t s 16, 23, 75 1 U Ž . t s 10, 23, 75 2 U Ž . t s 10, 23, 100 3 U Ž . t s 10, 23, 125 4 U Ž . t s 10, 17, 125 5 U U Ž 4. The tariff rates t and t represent the extreme ranges of the constraints t , 1 5 1 . t , E : 2 M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463]495 488 U Ž . t s high , high, low 1 U Ž . t s low , low, high 5 Ž U . and yield, as expected, maximum revenue]minimum equity t and minimum 1 Ž U . revenue]maximum equity t measures. 5 A Ž . 5. The Armenian tariff t s 13, 20, 100 is non-Pareto-efficient. Ž . 6. The mean and variance decreases within each tariff class t , t , E as E 1 2 Ž . increases t and t held fixed , while the skewness remains essentially 1 2 constant and the kurtosis measure increases. . Ž . In the flat-rate tariff, revenue R R t , f and E g was directly proportional to t, and thus, directly proportional to one another. In the two-tier tariff, revenue is now Ž . Ž . a function of three parameters, but R R t ,f and E g still depict a general increasing trend. This is illustrated in Fig. 9 and can be seen in Table 6 within each Ž . Ž tariff class t ,t ,? as a function of E . Note that as E increases from 75 to 100 1 2 . Ž . Ž . to 125 kWh , revenue R R t ,f decreases along with the value of E g . The slope of the data in each tariff rate class provides a measure of the sensitivity of the total Ž . revenue to changes in g; e.g. for 10, 17,? , Ž . D R R t , f 911 302 y 660 020 5 s s 1.0 = 10 Dg 7.2 y 4.7 Ž . while for 10, 20,? , Ž . D R R t , f 1 046 022 y 956 240 4 s s 8.9 = 10 Dg 8.0 y 7.0 These sensitivity measures can be used to compare the various tariff rates. Ž . Ž . The relationship between R R t , f and sk g for the 27 tariff rate combinations is depicted in Fig. 10. In Fig. 11 the 27 tariff combinations in Table 6 are plotted relative to the Ž . revenue and equity they generate columns 2 and 5 in Table 6 . The efficient frontier is illustrated in Fig. 12 and depicts the Pareto-optimal tariff rates. A Pareto-optimal tariff rate t U is defined such that no other tariff rate is at least as good as t U on every objective and strictly better than t U on at least one objective. In this setting the objectives are revenue and equity, and the tariff rates t U , i i s 1, . . . ,5, are the Pareto-optimal tariffs. The same general trend between rev- Ž . Ž . enue R R t ,f and equity E E t , f is observed as the flat rate but the structure is complicated by the non-linear nature of the tariff. As the revenue increases, the equity measure decreases, but there are a number of combinations that are Ž non-efficient and can be improved either with an increase in the revenue or . A Ž . equity . The Armenian tariff t s 13, 20, 100 , for example, falls in this classifica- U Ž . tion and is thus a non-optimal tariff. Observe that the tariff t s 10, 23, 125 4 increases the equity measure as compared to t A by nearly 15 while not changing M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 489 Ž . Ž . Ž . Fig. 9. Graph of the total revenue R R t , f vs. the mean value E g for the 27 tariff combinations t s t , t , E t s 10, 1 2 1 4 13, 16; t s 17, 20, 23; E s 75, 100, 125 . 2 M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 490 Ž . Ž . Ž . Fig. 10. Graph of the total revenue R R t ,f vs. the skewness sk g for the 27 tariff combinations t s t , t , E t s 10, 1 2 1 4 13, 16; t s 17, 20, 23; E s 75, 100, 125 . 2 M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463 ] 495 491 Ž . Ž . Ž . Fig. 11. Graph of the total revenue R R t , f vs. the equity H 0.1 for the 27 tariff combinations t s t ,t , E t s 10, 13, 16; t 1 2 1 4 t s 17, 20, 23; E s 75, 100, 125 . 2 M.J. Kaiser r Energy Economics 22 2000 463]495 492 U Ž . the revenue generated. The tariff t s 10, 23, 75 is observed to increase revenue 2 by 12 and equity by 3. This result follows from the fact that t U and t U are 2 4 elements of the efficient frontier, while t A is not. 5.3. Optimization model formulation The rates t U and t U represent the extreme ranges of the constraints and can be 1 5 solved for in terms of an optimization model. In particular, t U and t U tariff designs 1 5 represent the solution to the constrained optimization problems: Ž . max g t , f s.t. 10 F t F 16 1 Ž . 17 F t F 23 2 Ž . 75 F E F 125 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . for g t , f s R R t , f and g t , f s E E t , f , respectively. The Pareto-optimal tariffs t U , t U , t U can also be solved for directly using a linear programming formulation, 2 3 4 and for the two objective case, a visual solution is straightforward. The framework of optimization theory, however, allows the problem class to be generalized in significant directions.

6. Conclusions