EQUILIBRIUM, SDF AND THE EULER EQUATIONS ∗
9.7 EQUILIBRIUM, SDF AND THE EULER EQUATIONS ∗
We have seen, throughout Chapters 5, 6 and 7, the importance of the rational expectations hypothesis as a concept of equilibrium for determining asset prices. In Chapter 3, we have also used the maximization of the expected utility of consumption to determine a rationality leading to a pricing mechanism we have called the SDF (stochastic discount factor). In other words, while in rational expectations we have an asset price determined by:
Current price =
E ∗ {Future Prices}
1+R f
where E ∗ denotes expectation with respect to a ‘subjective’ probability (in J. Muth, 1961 words) which we called the risk-neutral probability and R f is the risk-free rate. In the SDF framework, we had:
Current price = E ∗ Future Prices
In this section, we extend the two-period framework used in Chapter 3 to multiple periods. To do so, we shall use Euler’s equation, providing the condition for an equilibrium based on a rationality of expected utility of consumption. Let an investor maximizing the expected utility of consumption:
where u(c t+j ) is the utility of consumption at time t + j, T is the final time and
G (W T ) is the terminal wealth state at time T . At time t, the change rate in the wealth is:
WW
c t+j and therefore c +R t t+j −W t −1 t =q t t −R t t+j =
q t+j We insert this last expression in the utility to be maximized:
Application of Euler’s equation, a necessary condition for value maximization, yields:
t+j
W t+j
INCOMPLETE MARKETS AND STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY
and therefore we have the following ‘equilibrium’: ∂ V t
= q W = constant or =E ρ
q t+j W t+j In other words, the marginal utility of wealth increments (savings) equals the dis-
t+j t+j t+j
W t + j−1
counted inflation-adjusted marginal utilities of consumption. If wealth is invested in a portfolio of assets such that:
N t+j and therefore, ∂ u (c t + j−1 )
N t+j since at time t−1, the future price at time t is random, we have:
where M t is the kernel, or the stochastic discount factor, expressing the ‘con- sumption impatience’. This equation can also be written as follows:
1+R t = ;1=E M t p t → 1 = E {M (1 + R t t }
t −1
p t −1
which is the standard form of the SDF equation.
Example: The risk-free rate
If p t is a bond worth $1 at time t, then for a risk-free discount rate:
= E {M t } (1) and therefore E {M t }=
1+R f 1+R f This leads to: M t
and finally to p t −1 =E
1+R f where E ∗ t is a modified (subjective) probability distribution.
(c
t + j−1
SELECTED TOPICS
Example: Risk premium and the CAPM beta
For a particular risky asset, the CAPM provides a linear discount mechanism which is:
M t +1 =a t +b t R M,t +1
In other words, for a given stock, whose rate of return is 1 + R t +1 =p t +1 / p t , we have:
1 cov (M t +1 , 1+R t +1 )
1 = E {M t +1 (1 + R t +1 )} → E(1 + R t +1 )= −
E (M t +1 ) and therefore, upon introducing the linear SDF, we have:
E (M t +1 ) After we insert the linear model for the kernel we have:
E (M t +1 )
E (1 + R t +1 ) = (1 + R f,t ) [1 − cov (M t +1 , 1+R t +1 )] and
E (1 + R t +1 ) = (1 + R f,t +1 )[1 − cov(a + bR M,t +1 , 1+R t +1 )] which is reduced to:
cov(R M,t +1 −R f,t +1 , R −R )
var(R
E (R t +1 −R f,t +1 )=βE t (R M,t +1 −R f,t +1 )
However, the hypothesis that the kernel is linear may be limiting. Recent studies have suggested that we use a quadratic measurement of risk with a kernel given by:
t +1 =a t +b t R M,t +1 +c t R M,t +1
In this case, the skewness of the distribution also enters into the determination of the value of the stock.