Extensions Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:L:Labour Economics:Vol7.Issue2.Mar2000:

expected future profit. In fact, as the above discussion of lifetime wage maximiza- tion implies, the increase in the first-period wage exceeds the expected gain in second-period profit, so expected profits fall. Wages rise in the first period to offset the expected differential between firm profits which widens both because firm e period 2 profits rise and firm c period 2 profits fall. Proposition 7: a If the cost of specific inÕestment is prohibitiÕely high, so s U s 0, the expected second-period wage conditional on remaining with firm e equals the expected second-period wage conditional on moÕing to firm c; b As the cost of specific inÕestment goes to zero, s U approaches the maximum match differential. In the limit, the expected wage of stayers equals Eu q g U , which is U exceeded by the expected wage of moÕers, u q g ; c For intermediate Õalues of the cost of specific inÕestment, the expected wage of moÕers may be less than or greater than the expected wage of stayers. As the cost of specific investment decreases, the level of investment increases, and eventually the expected wage of movers exceeds that of stayers: sorting across firms leads to substantial wage gains for movers. Ever since the work of Jovanovic Ž . 1979a , the question, of what portion of the estimated coefficients on firm tenure variables in wage regressions is due to true ‘tenure effects’ — such as specific human capital accumulation — and what portion is simply the effect of better matches being more durable, has been vigorously debated. Typically in the underlying theory, specific capital accrues mechanically. One might think that had an empirical measure of specific capital investment been available, a finding that the wages of movers rose more than those of stayers would show that workers do not share in the returns to specific capital, and preclude this explanation of firm tenure effects. This proposition cautions against such an interpretation: the relative wage of movers and stayers can fall or rise when the cost of specific investment falls. A full examination of tenure effects requires a multiperiod model.

3. Extensions

3.1. Cross-firms Õariations in inÕestment productiÕity So far, I have assumed that the two firms are symmetric in the opportunities they offer workers for acquiring human capital. Consider instead what would happen if the productivity of a worker’s investment were different across firms. Ž . Cross-firm differences in the cost of investment would have a similar effect. If employment at one firm allows a worker to accumulate more general skills per unit of investment than employment at the other, all workers would choose to work at the more productive firm. Workers discount the initial wage offer from the less productive firm. In equilibrium, the initial wage the high productivity firm must pay to attract the worker is equal to the wage that makes the low productivity firm indifferent to hiring the worker, minus the additional net income the worker expects to earn in period 2 from her higher general skill productivity. Compared to the symmetric case of Section 2, the ‘losing’ firm c and the worker are no better or worse off, and the ‘winning’ firm, e, earns higher profits. The additional profit to firm e is simply the market value of its superior technology for providing general skills to workers. The principle difference is that all workers choose the same initial employer. If instead specific capital investment is more efficient at one firm, but general investments are symmetric, a similar situation results. All workers choose employ- ment at the more efficient firm, the initial wage is set by the indifference condition of the losing bidder, and so the additional surplus from more productive invest- ment technology accrues to the firm which owns it. This highlights the fact, obscured by the symmetry assumed in Section 2, that it is the potential value of the specific investment at the losing firm which causes wages to rise in the first period. 3.2. Informed inÕestment Consider the effect of a worker learning her match at firm e before she undertakes any investment. Such knowledge does not affect the general invest- ment: because the expected second-period wage for all matches of worker rises dollar for dollar with the value of general skills, match quality does not enter the worker’s decision. On the other hand, the return to specific capital is match-depen- dent, and therefore, so is the investment decision. In Section 2, I assumed that firm c learns its match before bidding for the worker in the second period. Alterna- tively, one might assume that this information is available only after winning the worker. In this case, firm c can do no better than to raise its bid up to the expected value of the worker. In either case, the following proposition holds. Proposition 8: If at the time of inÕestment workers know their match quality at firm e, then workers inÕest more in general capital than in specific capital, and the specific inÕestment is a non-increasing function of match quality, i.e.: g U s U u 0; Ž . e and Es U u Ž . e F 0. Eu e The worker weighs her investment in specific capital by the probability of turnover, which is always less than one, so she invests more in general than specific skills. Now, however, the weight differs across matches: since the because the probability of turnover decreases in match quality, so does investment in specific capital. This result is the opposite of what one would expect in a model with exogenous turnover in which the workers least likely to leave invest most in Ž . 5 specific capital see, e.g., Jovanovic, 1979b . A worker with a poorer match at firm e invests more in specific capital than one with a better match, but not so much more as to fully offset the difference in match quality. This makes sense: if a poorly matched worker did fully compensate for the difference in match quality, she would face the same probability of turnover as the good worker. But then the marginal benefit of the last unit of specific capital would have yielded the same expected return to the two workers, and yet have entailed a higher marginal cost for the poorer-matched worker. Thus, if the better worker were investing optimally, the poorer worker would be overinvesting. As the general investment does not affect the probability of turnover, this leads to the following result. 6 Proposition 9: If at the time of inÕestment workers know their match at firm e, the probability of turnoÕer and the worker inÕestment in human capital are positiÕely correlated. 3.3. Free entry Suppose that there are is an infinite number of employers, each of which can for a cost k participate in auctions for the worker’s services. Then there is a mixed strategy equilibrium in which each potential competitor enters with sufficient Ž . probability that the expected gross profit for every competitor is equal to k. Let n denote the expected number of firms competing for worker in the second 2 period. Notice that n decreases in k. 2 The effect of the general human capital investment is unchanged from the model above: the identity of the winner and runner-up in the competition for the worker is immaterial. When workers invest in specific capital, expected second- period wages are bid-up in the event that firm e has the second highest valuation, which occurs with positive probability, so some such investment occurs. Similarly, a wedge between the expected profit of the employer and any other second-period 5 The result that the investment in general capital is independent of match quality arises because of the separability of both the cost and productivity of general and specific capital. If the costs of investment were such that increases in specific investment raised the cost of general investment, say because the worker faces a time constraint, then poorly matched workers would invest less in general skills. 6 Notice that this does not predict that oÕerall investment is positively correlated with turnover, as investment by firms is not included. Firms prefer to invest most in workers for which the probability of turnover is lowest. competitor exists, so period 1 wage competition intensifies. However, the wedge is less than in Section 2, since firm e only captures the additional and the surplus when it has the best of the n matches, and the competitors earn zero in all cases. 2 The more firms that enter, the smaller are each of these effects. However, for any positive k, the main results from Section 2 are obtained. Workers are willing to invest some positive amount in specific skills, and because the employer also gains from this, period 1 wages are bid-up. Because of the zero-profit constraint, the worker receives the whole of firm e’s expected second-period profit as a transfer in the first period. The most important difference is that the whole value of specific capital declines as k gets small. So while from a career perspective workers still invest too little in specific capital, the lifetime optimal amount decreases as k falls, and so may be less than the optimal general investment. Further characterizations depend on the match distribution.

4. Conclusion