Contributions and Implications for Practice and Theory

Contributions and Implications for Practice and Theory

The current research provides several insights that should

be of relevance to academics and managers. First, we high-

118 / Journal of Marketing, September 2013

TABLE 3 Dependent Variable: Royalty Rate

Variables

OLS Estimate (SE)

IPRP (H 1 )

–.95 (.45)*

Market size (H 2 )

.39 (.08)*

IPRP ¥ market size (H 3 )

UA ¥ market size (H 5 )

.44 (.35)

Contract duration (H 6 )

–.25 (.07)*

Exclusivity (H 7 )

–.70 (.18)*

Sales guarantee (H 8 )

.25 (.19)

Advance payment (H 9 )

.09 (.25)

Minimum payment (H 10 )

.44 (.17)*

Brand reputation

–.38 (.23)

Licensor capability

–.25 (.17)

Multiple country dummy

.05 (.16)

* p < .05.

FIGURE 2 Interaction Effect of IPRP and Market Size on Royalty Rate

Low IPRP High IPRP

Low market size High market size

Brand Licensing: What Drives Royalty Rates? / 119

light the importance of global brand licensing to marketers as a strategic tool. Given the higher economic growth rates in various countries outside the United States, many of them in emerging markets, marketers need to have a better understanding of this brand development strategy. As more firms are “born global” and have an immediate Internet presence available to consumers worldwide, the importance of expeditiously registering their IP (e.g., brands) abroad and using their brands in overseas markets to retain rights to the brand makes licensing a potentially much more relevant tool. This is even more important given that small firms with great brand potential may initially have fewer internal resources to develop their brands overseas. A new firm might opt to license its brand in strategic overseas markets to simultaneously build and protect its brand.

Second, we highlight the role of concerns about protect- ing the brand in brand licensing. Although the marketing field considers protection of brand assets important— indeed, Day (2011) suggests that it is a strategic imperative for marketers—academic research has not paid much atten- tion to this issue. In this article, we explain brand protection more broadly, not only as involving a brand’s protection against mishandling by others but also as the need to safe- guard rights in foreign markets through active brand use. The failure to do so can result in brand owners needing to buy back their brand names in these markets, leading to unexpected delays and increased cost. We discuss brand protection as an underlying concern in the context of global brand licensing and explore its role in shaping royalty rate. Quelch (1985) observes that under certain circumstances, managers should be prepared to trade off revenue against the need to protect the brand. In this article, we discuss some conditions under which these circumstances may occur.

Third, we emphasize the role of IPRP in brand manage- ment. Although it is evident that the extent to which IP is protected in a market has a significant impact on a firm’s ability to prevent misuse of its property, the marketing lit- erature has not provided much attention to this issue. We address this gap.

Fourth, this article examines how royalty rate varies across international markets on the basis of market charac- teristics. As we noted previously, efforts to explain such variation are rare, even in the more well-established related franchising literature. We hope that our preliminary effort in this regard spurs interest in this topic.

Fifth, although prior research has examined franchising, it differs from licensing in that the franchisor has much more control over the franchisee, which must adopt the franchisor’s business model completely. Brand licensing, in comparison, does not involve adoption of the business model and may span product categories and markets that are both familiar and unfamiliar to the licensor. Our article examines how licensors attempt to protect the brand through a business arrangement in which they have less control over the brand’s management.

Implications for Licensors and Licensees

The results show how brand licensors can use IPRP to assess the risk their brand faces in a global market, evaluate

the need for monitoring, and adjust royalty rates on the basis of such an assessment. Brand licensors can also gain insights into how market size can be used to negotiate higher royalty rates. Licensees can gain deeper understand- ing of licensor motivations, which will help them shape durable and more successful contracts. The results also pro- vide information about the relationships between the vari- ous contract characteristics that influence royalty rates. Thus, firms may gain some insight into how various choices made in structuring brand licensing contracts can influence royalty rates. Overall, the study sheds light on factors that enable licensors and licensees to balance their interests in the context of brand licensing.

The findings are particularly useful to licensors, because they demonstrate how brand licensing may differ from technology licensing. In technology licensing, licen- sors offer low royalty rates as an incentive to limit licensee moral hazard when IPRP is low (Park and Lippoldt 2005). In brand licensing, our results show that the reverse may be the case: higher royalty rates prevail when IPRP is low because the risk to the brand and the accompanying costs of monitoring are greater. As one of the executives we inter- viewed noted, “If you lose control of things, you run the risk of diluting your brand,” referring to the need to care- fully monitor licensee activities in such markets. Higher costs of monitoring can arise in the case of brands because they can be more easily violated or misappropriated; in con- trast, technical expertise is required to copy a technology. Higher costs of monitoring a brand could also be a conse- quence of its longer life as an asset compared with the life of a technology patent. This result must be further clarified through direct testing of technology licensing and brand licensing contracts.

From our results, firms concerned with committing sig- nificant capital by entering markets with poor IPPR may consider entering these markets by licensing and “manag- ing” their risk. Although these markets carry risk to a firm’s brands, if the risk is managed through greater monitoring supported by higher royalty rates, the benefits may out- weigh the risks. Brand managers, in this regard, might con- sider collaborating with corporate risk managers at their companies to build their foreign market entry strategies.

Implications for Theory

Our results show how licensors and licensees can protect their interests while structuring brand licensing contracts. From a theoretical perspective, the study illustrates the two- sided nature of agency issues in brand licensing agree- ments, particularly for international contracts. Although economics literature has addressed two-sided agency issues (e.g., Lafontaine 1992), these issues have not received much attention in the marketing literature. The two-sided agency formulation employed here shows situations in which the principal is not risk averse and in which both the principal and the agent take their relative risk into account while structuring agency contracts. A key contribution of this research is its extension of agency theory to a context in which the principal and agent interact to manage an intangi- ble asset. In addition, the use of actual contract data to Our results show how licensors and licensees can protect their interests while structuring brand licensing contracts. From a theoretical perspective, the study illustrates the two- sided nature of agency issues in brand licensing agree- ments, particularly for international contracts. Although economics literature has addressed two-sided agency issues (e.g., Lafontaine 1992), these issues have not received much attention in the marketing literature. The two-sided agency formulation employed here shows situations in which the principal is not risk averse and in which both the principal and the agent take their relative risk into account while structuring agency contracts. A key contribution of this research is its extension of agency theory to a context in which the principal and agent interact to manage an intangi- ble asset. In addition, the use of actual contract data to

This study emphasizes the need to protect marketing assets. Brand violation devalues the brand, compromises revenues, and reduces a marketer’s ability to fully leverage the equity of the brand (Day 2011). Therefore, the protec- tion of brand property must be given importance in the dis- cussion of marketing assets. Relatedly, our results highlight concerns that arise in the management of intangible assets, which can be more easily misused. It is expensive and diffi- cult to monitor these violations. As one licensing executive told us, “Dilution of the brand is the biggest risk [in licens- ing].” Importantly, although we do not directly test this, our findings imply that, in the context of licensing, not all intan- gible assets can be treated similarly. For example, brand assets may need more protection than technology assets because of their longer-term value and relative ease of vio- lation. In an era of global brand management, when brand assets are often the most significant part of a firm’s value (Day 2011), it is important to evaluate strategies to protect such assets.

Limitations and Directions for Further Research

The study is based on cross-sectional data, which typically limits the ability to draw causal conclusions. However, this is not a critical issue in the context of this study, because our objective is to analyze the variation in royalty rate on the basis of market characteristics that influence risk percep- tions of both the licensor and the licensee. A cross-sectional comparison is more feasible in this context, especially because some of the country characteristics we consider do not change much over the relatively short time frames.

We could not obtain brand reputation measures for all brands in our data set from secondary sources. This led to our decision to use industry experts to rate the brands. The strong correlations of the expert assessment of brand repu- tation with archival measures of market share for those brands (where such measures were available) should allevi- ate concerns of the validity of this measure. Furthermore, we obtained multiple raters for nearly all the brands included in the study. Regardless, we did not offer hypothe- ses for the impact of brand reputation on royalty rate. We were also unable to obtain fine-grained measures for market sizes for specific brands in the country markets where they were licensed. Instead, we relied on GDP to assess market size. Not all the contracts were drawn up for operation in a single country. Although we tried to limit the data to con- tracts drawn for similar countries and used a dummy variable to rule out whether multicountry contracts had an effect on the results, it would be ideal to use only single- country contracts. These are issues that must be addressed in further research, especially given the relatively small sample size used in this study.

We did not find support for hypotheses regarding the influence of UA (H 4 –H 5 ), and it is possible that this result is due to weaknesses in the measure. We decided to use Hof- stede’s (1980) measure partly because the measures have repeatedly been subjected to replication and have typically

been found to have validity (Brock et al. 2008; Husted 1999; Shackleton and Ali 1990; Sondergaard 1994). How- ever, there is ample criticism of Hofstede’s measures, and using the index values at the country level may not have enabled us to adequately measure culture at the level of the individual respondent or firm. Further research exploring the impact of culture on licensing contracts would benefit from primary data from actual respondents rather than the use of an aggregate measure.

Using data from licensing contracts, we find evidence that supports a two-sided moral hazard argument based on agency theory. However, due to limited data availability, we could not examine the conditions under which different payment structures, such as fixed fees and royalty rates, are used. We had no contracts that employed a fixed fee pay- ment in our data. However, there are contracts in other areas of licensing, such as technology licensing, that employ fixed-fee payment structures. Fixed payments are also more popular when licensed products are components in a system and individual sales for the licensed products are difficult to establish (Johnson 2001). It is also possible that competi- tiveness of the category and distribution channel structure could influence royalty rate because the licensee competes to stay financially viable. Further research is warranted here.

By collecting primary data, researchers can examine the relative impact of the motivation to protect the brand and enhance revenues on royalty rates. In this study, an under- lying postulate is that the negative impact of IPRP on roy- alty rates is driven by the licensor’s desire to protect the brand. Although our findings lend credence to this assump- tion, a direct test of the relative roles of brand protection and revenue generation will help managers gain greater insights into the interplay between these two (sometimes conflicting) objectives in brand licensing. In addition, we suggest that royalty rates increase with market size because of the licensee’s desire to ensure support from the licensor.

A direct test of this premise through primary data will help shed further light on the incentive-alignment process that shapes brand licensing contracts. Finally, an assessment of the impact of licensor and licensee characteristics on moral hazard concerns through the collection of primary data will help confirm and extend the findings from this research.

From a public policy perspective, there is a concern that strong IPRP will shift income to IP-exporting countries and might affect the establishment of such regimes in a country (Maskus 2000). Notably, in this study, we find that higher IPRP benefits firms in the importer nation because the licensee is likely to receive a lower royalty rate. As such, brand licensees should retain more of their earnings when the IP regime in their country provides adequate protection to IP rights. A direct empirical assessment of this strategy should be of interest to public policy scholars.

Directly contrasting brand and technology licensing will also provide insights into how the nature of IP affects the appropriability of returns. The influence of IPRP on licens- ing may vary by product characteristics, particularly the content and boundaries of knowledge that is protected (Anand and Khanna 2000; Park and Lippoldt 2005). Although Park and Lippoldt (2005) demonstrate how differ- ent types of IP regulations influence revenues from IP, more

120 / Journal of Marketing, September 2013 120 / Journal of Marketing, September 2013

text. However, a deeper understanding of the nature of these Ambler (2003) notes that brand management involves

compromises and their contextual variations is required to trade-offs between leveraging the brand to enhance cash

provide brand managers with appropriate guidance in lever- flows and preventing the brand from dilution. This study

aging and sustaining their brand.

REFERENCES

Agrawal, Deepak and Rajiv Lal (1995), “Contractual Arrange- Dunning, John H. (1993), Multinational Enterprises and the ments in Franchising: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of

Global Economy . Boston: Addison-Wesley. Marketing Research , 32 (May), 213–21.

Fladmoe-Lindquist, Karin (1996), “International Franchising: Ambler, Tim (2003), Marketing and the Bottom Line: The Market-

Capabilities and Development,” Journal of Business Venturing, ing Metrics That Will Pump Up Cash Flow , 2d ed. Harlow,

UK: FT Prentice Hall. Fraley, Melissa (2004), “We Are Not So Different After All,” Bot- Anand, Bharat N. and Tarun Khanna (2000), “The Structure of

tomLine , (Winter), 4.

Licensing Contracts,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 48 (1), Friedman, Neil (2004), “A Perspective on Toy Licensing,” Bot- 103–135.

tomLine , (Winter), 1.

Asiedu, Elizabeth and Hadi Saleh Esfahani (2001), “Ownership Garg, Vinay K. and Abdul A. Rasheed (2003), “International Structure in Foreign Direct Investment Projects,” Review of

Multi-Unit Franchising: An Agency Theoretic Explanation,” Economics and Statistics , 83 (4), 647–62.

International Business Review , 12 (3), 329–48. Bass, Adam (2004), “Licensed Extensions—Stretching to Com-

Gillespie, Kate, Kishore Krishna, and Susan Jarvis (2002), “Pro- municate,” Brand Management, 12 (1), 31–38.

tecting Global Brands: Towards a Global Norm,” Journal of Battersby, Gregory J. and Danny Simon (2010), Basics of Licens-

International Marketing , 10 (2), 99–112. ing: How to Extend Brand and Entertainment Properties for

Ginarte, Juan Carlos and Walter G. Park (1997), “Determinants of Profit . Norwalk, CT: Kent Press.

Patent Rights: A Cross-National Study,” Research Policy, 26 Bharadwaj, Sundar G., Kapil R. Tuli, and Andre Bonfrer (2011),

“The Impact of Brand Quality on Shareholder Wealth,” Jour- Gorgo, Paolo (2011), “Jamba Juice Foreign Expansion and nal of Marketing , 75 (September), 88–104.

Licensing Strategy Seems on Track,” SeekingAlpha.com, Bhattacharyya, Sugato and Francine Lafontaine (1995), “Double-

(September 20), (accessed May 31, 2013), [available at Sided Hazard and the Nature of Share Contracts,” RAND Jour-

http://seekingalpha.com/article/294714-jamba-juice-foreign- nal of Economics , 26 (4), 761–81.

expansion-and-licensing-strategy-seems-on-track]. Brickley, James A. (2002), “Royalty Rates and Upfront Fees in

Grewal, Rajdeep and Ravi Dharwadkar (2002), “The Role of the Share Contracts: Evidence from Franchising,” Journal of Law,

Institutional Environment in Marketing Channels,” Journal of Economics, & Organization , 18 (2), 511–35.

Marketing , 66 (July), 82–97.

Brock, David M., Oded Shenkar, Amir Shoham, and Ilene C. Sis- Hofstede, Geert (1980), Culture’s Consequences: International covick (2008), “National Culture and Expatriate Deployment,”

Differences in Work-Related Values . Newbury Park, CA: Sage Journal of International Business Studies , 39 (8), 1293–1309.

Publications.

Caves, Richard E. (1996), Multinational Enterprise and Economic Husted, Bryan W. (1999), “Wealth, Culture, and Corruption,” Analysis , 2d ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Journal of International Business Studies , 30 (2), 339–59. ———, Harold Crookell, and J. Peter Killing (1983), “The Imper-

International Business Center (2011), “Geert Hofstede TM Cultural fect Market for Technology Licenses,” Oxford Bulletin of Eco-

Dimensions,” (accessed June 3, 2013), [available at http:// nomics and Statistics , 45 (3) 249–67.

www. international-business-center.com/geert-hofstede/ geert_ Choo, Stephen (2005), “Determinants of Monitoring Capabilities

hofstede_resources.shtml].

in International Franchising: Foodservice Firms Within East International Monetary Fund (2007), “World Economic Outlook Asia,” Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 22 (2), 159–77.

Database,” (accessed June 3, 2013), [available at http://www. Chui, Andy C.W. and Chuck C.Y. Kwok (2008), “National Culture

imf. org/ external/pubs/ft/weo/2007/02/weodata/index.aspx]. and Life Insurance Consumption,” Journal of the International

Jackson, Gregory and Richard Deeg (2008), “From Comparing Business Studies , 39 (1), 88–101.

Capitalism to the Politics of Institutional Change,” Review of Colucci, Mariachiara, Elisa Montaguti, and Umberto Lago (2008),

International Political Economy , 15 (4), 680–709. “Brand Extension Through Licensing: An Investigation into

Jensen, Michael C. and William Meckling (1976), “Theory of the the High-End Fashion Industry,” International Journal of

Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Research in Marketing , 25 (2), 129–37.

Behavior,” Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (4), 305–360. Conrad, Bill (2011), “Bottling Plant Creates Legal Defense Fund,”

Johnson, Howard E. (2001), “Establishing Royalty Rates in Star Local News , (September 19), (accessed June 3, 2013),

Licensing Agreements,” CMA Management, 75 (1), 16–19. [available at http://www.scntx.com/articles/2011/09/19/ news_

Johnson, Simon, John McMillan, and Christopher Woodruff update/9595.txt].

(2002), “Property Rights and Finance,” American Economic Dant, Rajiv P. and Nada Nasr (1998), “Control Techniques and

Review , 92 (5), 1335–56.

Upward Flow of Information in Franchising in Distant Mar- Kallapur, Sanjay and Sabrina Y.S. Kwan (2004), “The Value Rele- kets: Conceptualization and Preliminary Evidence,” Journal of

vance and Reliability of Brand Assets Recognized by U.K. Business Venturing , 13 (1), 3–28.

Firms,” Accounting Review, 79 (1), 151–72. ———, Rozenn Perrigot, and Gerard Cliquet (2008), “A Cross-

Kashyap, Vishal, Kersi D. Antia, and Gary L. Frazier (2012), Cultural Comparison of the Plural Forms in Franchise Net-

“Contracts, Extracontractual Incentives, and Ex Post Behavior works: United States, France, and Brazil,” Journal of Small

in Franchise Channel Relationships,” Journal of Marketing Business Management , 46 (2), 286–311.

Research , 49 (April), 260–76.

Day, George (2011), “Closing the Marketing Capabilities Gap,” Kaufman, Patrick J. and Rajiv P. Dant (2001), “The Pricing of Journal of Marketing , 75 (July), 183–95.

Franchise Rights,” Journal of Retailing, 77 (4), 537–46.

Brand Licensing: What Drives Royalty Rates? / 121

Kostova, Tatiana and Sreelata Zaheer (1999), “Organizational Quelch, John A. (1985), “How to Build a Product Licensing Pro- Legitimacy Under Conditions of Complexity: The Case of the

gram,” Harvard Business Review, 63 (3), 186–93. Multinational Enterprise,” Academy of Management Review,

Reily, Stephen R. (2001a), “Licensing Agreements: Partnerships 24 (1), 64–81.

Worth Getting Right,” The Licensing Letter, (September), Kramer, Andrew E. (2007), “After a Long Dispute, a Russian Star-

(accessed June 3, 2013), [available at http://www.imcpartner- bucks,” The New York Times, (September 7), (accessed June 3,

ships. com/2001/09/license-agreements-partnerships-worth- 2013), [available at www.nytimes.com/2007/09/07/business/

getting-right/].

worldbusiness/07sbux.html]. ——— (2001b), “Trademark Licensing,” Licensing Journal, 22 Lafontaine, Francine (1992), “Agency Theory and Franchising:

(8), 23–24.

Some Empirical Results,” RAND Journal of Economics, 23 (2), Roth, Kendall and Sharon O’Donnell (1996), “Foreign Subsidiary 263–83.

Compensation Strategy: An Agency Theory Perspective,” ——— and Joanne Oxley (2001), “International Franchising: Evi-

Academy of Management Journal , 39 (3), 678–703. dence from U.S. and Canadian Franchisors in Mexico,” Work-

Scott, W. Richard (1995), Institutions and Organizations (Founda- ing Paper No. 8179, National Bureau of Economic Research.

tions for Organizational Science) . Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage ——— and Kathryn L. Shaw (1999), “The Dynamics of Franchise

Publications.

Contracting: Evidence from Panel Data,” Journal of Political Shackleton, Viv J. and Abbas H. Ali (1990), “Work-Related Values Economy , 107 (5), 1041–80.

of Managers: A Test of the Hofstede Model,” Journal of Cross- Lieberstein, Marc and Tywanda Harris Lord (2010), “Licensing

Cultural Psychology , 21 (1), 109–118. Your Brand in China: Guidelines for Brand Owners,” Intellec-

Shane, Scott A. (1998), “Making New Franchise Systems Work,” tual Property Litigation , 22 (1), 3–7.

Strategic Management Journal , 19 (7), 697–707. Lisanti, Tony (2011), “Top 125 Global Licensors,” License!

——— and Maw-De Foo (1999), “New Firm Survival: Institutional Global , (May), (accessed June 3, 2013), [available at http://

Explanations for New Firm Mortality,” Management Science, digital.licensemag.com/nxtbooks/advanstar/license0511/#/46].

45 (2), 142–59.

——— (2013), “Top 150 Global Licensors,” License! Global, Sherman, Andrew J. (2004), Franchising & Licensing: Two Pow- (May), (accessed June 10, 2013), [available at http:// images2.

erful Ways to Grow Your Business in Any Economy , 3d ed. New advanstar.com/PixelMags/license-global/digitaledition/05-

York: AMACOM.

2013-sp.html#2]. Sondergaard, Mikael (1994), “Research Note: Hofstede’s Conse- Managing Intellectual Property (2010), “Australia’s Top Court

quences: A Study of Reviews, Citations and Replications,” Boosts Brand Owners,” INTA Daily News: 132nd Annual

Organization Studies , 15 (3) 447–56. Meeting, Boston , (May 24), (accessed June 3, 2013), [available

Srivastava, Rajendra K., Tasadduq A. Shervani, and Liam Fahey at http://www.managingip.com/pdfs/02_inta_boston_mon.pdf].

(1999), “Marketing, Business Processes, and Shareholder Marron, Donald B. and David G. Steel (2000), “Which Countries

Value: An Organizationally Embedded View of Marketing Protect Intellectual Property? The Case of Software Piracy,”

Activities and the Discipline of Marketing,” Journal of Mar- Economic Inquiry , 38 (2), 159–74.

keting , 63 (October), 168–79.

Maskus, Keith E. (2000), “Lessons from Studying the Interna- Starbucks (2008), “Starbucks and Unilever Sign Licensing Agree- tional Economics of Intellectual Property Rights,” Vanderbilt

ment to Grow Super-Premium Starbucks Ice Cream Business,” Law Review , 53 (6), 2219–39.

press release, (September 15), (accessed May 31, 2013), [avail- McCandlish, Bob (2002), “Successful Licensing Means Letting

able at http://news.starbucks.com/article_display.cfm?article_ Go,” BottomLine, (Spring/Summer), 6.

id= 23].

Milgrom, Paul and John Roberts (1992), Economics, Organiza- Sunkist (2013), “Packaged Products,” (accessed June 3, 2013), tion, and Management . Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

[available at http://www.sunkist.com/products/licensed_products. Morgan, Neil A. and Lopo L. Rego (2009), “Brand Portfolio Strat-

aspx].

egy and Firm Performance,” Journal of Marketing, 73 (Janu- Van Voris, Bob (2011), “Starbucks Defeats Kraft’s Bid to Stop It ary), 59–74.

from Ending Deal,” Bloomberg.com, (January 28), (accessed ———, Rebecca J. Slotegraaf, and Douglas W. Vorhies (2009),

June 3, 2013), [available at http://www.bloomberg.com/news/ “Linking Marketing Capabilities with Profit Growth,” Interna-

2011-01-21/kraft-says-starbucks-breach-claims-are-frivolous- tional Journal of Research in Marketing , 26 (4), 284–93.

update1-.html].

North, Douglass (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Wiles, Michael A., Neil A. Morgan, and Lopo L. Rego (2012), Economic Performance . Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univer-

“The Effect of Brand Acquisition and Disposal on Stock sity Press.

Returns,” Journal of Marketing, 76 (January), 38–58. Park, Sojung Carol and Jean Lemaire (2011), “Culture Matters:

Wimmer, Bradley S. and John E. Garen (1997), “Moral Hazard, Long-Term Orientation and the Demand for Life Insurance,”

Asset Specificity, Implicit Bonding, and Compensation: The working paper, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.

Case of Franchising,” Economic Inquiry, 35 (3), 544–54. Park, Walter G. and Juan Carlos Ginarte (1997), “Intellectual

WIPO (2013), “Fields of Intellectual Property Protection,” in The Property Rights and Economic Growth,” Contemporary Eco-

Concept of Intellectual Property , Chap. 2, (accessed June 3, nomic Policy , 15 (3), 51–61.

2013), [available at http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/ www/ ——— and Douglas Lippoldt (2005), “International Licensing and

about-ip/en/ iprm/pdf/ch2.pdf].

the Strengthening of Intellectual Property Rights in Developing Xu, Dean and Oded Shenkar (2002), “Institutional Distance and Countries During the 1990s,” OECD Economic Studies, 40 (1),

the Multinational Enterprise,” Academy of Management 8–48.

Review , 27 (94), 608–618.

Penard, Thierry, Emmanuel Reynaud, and Stephane Saussier (2003), “Dual Distribution and Royalty Rates in Franchised Chains: An Empirical Analysis Using French Data,” Journal of Marketing Channels , 10 (3/4), 5–31.

122 / Journal of Marketing, September 2013

Dokumen yang terkait

EVALUASI PENERAPAN PSAK 109 TENTANG AKUNTANSI ZAKAT PADA LEMBAGA AMIL ZAKAT DI KABUPATEN MALANG (Studi pada lembaga amil zakat YATIM MANDIRI Kepanjen – Kabupaten Malang )

3 63 15

IMPLEMENTASI PSAK NO. 109 TENTANG AKUNTANSI ZAKAT DAN INFAK ATAU SEDEKAH PADA YAYASAN DANA SOSIAL AL FALAH KOTA MALANG

2 33 17

Event Marketing Sebagai Strategi Meningkatkan Brand Image Kabupaten Banyuwangi Melalui Event Banyuwangi Festival Tahun 2013

2 13 4

Pengaruh Mekanisme Corporate Governance, Spesialisasi Industri Auditor, Dan Audit Brand Name Terhadap Integritas Laporan Keuangan: Studi Empiris Pada Perusahaan Di Sektor Keuangan Yang Terdaftar Di Bursa Efek Indonesia Tahun 2010-2014

2 28 127

Kontribusi Performance, Switchig Cost, Trust In Brand Terhadap Kepuasan Pelanggan Serta Dampaknya Pada Loyalitas Pelanggan : studi kasus pada pengguna produk deodorant rexona di daerah Ciputat

0 8 192

Analisis pengaruh Brand Awareness, Perceived Quality, Brand Association, Dan Brand Loyalty terhadap keputusan pembelian pada produk pasta gigi 'Pepsodent (studi kasus pada Mahasiswa UIN Syarif Hidayatullah Jakarta)

6 41 167

Pengaruh Brand awareness, brand assosiation, perceived quality, dan brani image terhadap loyalitas konsumen sepeda motor honda : studi kasus pada mahasiswa uin syarif hidayatullah jakarta

0 9 112

Analisis Pengaruh Kualitas Produk, Brand Trust, Brand Image, dan Kepuasan Pelanggan terhadap Brand Loyality pada Air Meneral Aqua

3 43 162

Pengaruh Brand Image dan Atribut Produk Terhadap Pembelian Ulang Konsumen pada Garsel Shoes di Bandung

3 24 1

Perancangan Brand Awareness ARTBRZ (Art Breeze) Melalui Booklet

0 11 1