AKST Evolutions over Time: Thematic Narratives 87

60 | IAASTD Global Report high-value crops Allaire, 1996.This has enabled large sur- pluses of a narrow range of basic grains and protein foods to be generated, traded and also moved relatively quickly to meet emergency and humanitarian needs. It has eased hun- ger and reduced poverty as well as kept food prices stable and low relative to other prices and allowed investment in other economic sectors FAO, 2004. However, the ecologi- cal and cultural context of farming is always and necessarily “situated” and cannot—unlike functions such as water use or carbon trading—be physically exchanged Berkes and Folke, 1998; Hubert et al., 2000; Steffen et al., 2004; Lal et al., 2005; Pretty, 2005. Advances especially in the eco- logical sciences and socioeconomic research as well as driv- ers originating in civil society movements 2.2, 2.3 have mobilized science, knowledge and technology in support of approaches appreciative of place-speciic, multidimensional and multifunctional opportunities Agarwal et al., 1979; Byerlee, 1992; Symes and Jansen, 1994; Gilbert, 1995; de Boef, 2000; Fresco, 2002. Examples include Cohn et al., 2006, trading arrangements connecting those willing to pay for speciic ecological values and those who manage the resources that are valued Knight, 2007, urban councils using rate levies to pay farmers for the maintenance of sur- rounding recreational green space or for ecosystem services such as spreading lood water on their ields; hydroelectric companies such as Brazil-Iguacú paying farmers to practice conservation tillage to avoid silting behind the dams and improve communal water supplies; farmers’ markets; and community-supported agriculture. An embedded activity. The resulting lows of products and services are embedded in a web of institutional arrange- ments and relationships at varying scales, such as farmers’ organizations, industrial districts, commodity chains, ter- roirs, production areas, natural resource management ar- eas, ethnic territories, administrative divisions, nations and global trading networks. Farmers are simultaneously mem- bers of a variety of institutions and relationships that frame their opportunities and constraints, offering incentives and penalties that are sometimes contradictory; farmers require strategic ability to select and interpret the relevant informa- tion constituted in these institutions and relationships Chif- foleau and Dreyfus, 2004. The various ways of organizing science, knowledge and technology over the last sixty years have taken different approaches to farmers’ strategic roles see 2.1.2. A collective activity. Farmers are not wholly independent entrepreneurs; their livelihoods critically depend on rela- tionships that govern access to resources. With asymmetri- cal social relations, access is not equitably or evenly dis- tributed. Individuals, groups and communities attempt to cope with inequalities by developing relational skills and capacity for collective action that help them to protect or enhance their access to and use of resources Barbier and Lémery, 2000; the form that collective action takes changes over time and place and between genders. As commercial actors such as supermarkets have become dominant in food and farming systems, many farmers have transformed their production-oriented organizations into market-oriented organizations. actions are judged by current values or by those of only one set of actors. The drivers are assessed at three levels—local, regional, global. The assessments are further elaborated 2.3 in order to provide depth and detail in terms of three thematic narratives—1 genetic resources management; 2 pest management; 3 food system management. 2.1.1 The specificity of agriculture as an activity At the beginning of the period under assessment, policy makers and other knowledge actors around the world had vividly in mind the fact that food is a basic necessity of life and that its supply and distribution is vulnerable to a range of disruptions that cannot always be well controlled. Only for those for whom food is reliably abundant can food be treated as an industrial good subject to the laws of elastic- ity of price. The special characteristics of farming as a hu- man activity for supplying a basic necessity of life and as the cultural context of existence for a still large if declining proportion of the world’s people are central to meaningful historical assessment of AKST.

2.1.1.1 The characteristics of agriculture as a multidimensional activity

Agriculture is based on local management decisions made in interaction with the biophysical, ecological and social context, this context to a large extent itself evolving in- dependently of agriculture. It follows that AKST includes both a set of activities that happen to deal with the par- ticular domain of agriculture and activities that necessar- ily coevolve with numerous other changes in a society. AKST thus involves many types of knowledge and many suppliers of that knowledge acting in relation to vast num- bers of semi autonomous enterprises and decision mak- ers. This characteristic has provided special challenges but also opportunities in the design of institutional arrange- ments for AKST Yunus and Islam, 1975; Yunus, 1977; Izuno, 1979; Symes and Jansen, 1994; Scoones et al., 1996; Buck et al., 1998; Stroosnijder and Rheenen, 2001; Edgerton, 2007. A place-based activity. Agriculture as a place-based activity relies on unique combinations of bioclimatic conditions and local resources in their natural, socioeconomic and cultural dimensions. Agricultural practices depend on and also in- luence these conditions and resources Herdt and Mellor, 1964. Speciic knowledge of the locality is an asset deci- sive for the outcomes actually achieved through application of any technology Loomis and Beagle, 1950; Hill, 1982; Giller, 2002; Tittonell et al., 2005, 2007; Vanlauwe et al., 2006; Wopereis et al., 2006; Zingore et al., 2007 yet a dominant trend over the period is the evolution of agricul- tures driven by nonlocal changes and by the introduction of technologies designed by actors and in places far removed from their site of application Merton, 1957; Biggs, 1978; Anderson et al., 1991; Seur, 1992; Matson et al., 1997; Ha- rilal et al., 2006; Leach and Scoones, 2006. This trend has been tightly associated with the adoption of a science-based approach to the industrialization of farming. It has allowed greater control by farmers of production factors and the simpliication and homogenization of production situations particularly for internationally-traded commodities and