getdoc7888. 231KB Jun 04 2011 12:04:32 AM

(1)

El e c t ro n ic

Jo ur

n a l o

f P

r o

b a b il i t y Vol. 15 (2010), Paper no. 67, pages 2041–2068.

Journal URL

http://www.math.washington.edu/~ejpecp/

Martingale Property and Capacity under G-Framework

Jing Xu

School of Economics and Business Administration Chongqing University Chongqing 400030

Email:Xujing@yahoo.com.cn

Bo Zhang

Center for Applied Statistics and School of Statistics Renmin University of China, Beijing, 100872, P.R.China

Email:mabzhang@gmail.co

Abstract

The main purpose of this article is to study the symmetric martingale property and capacity defined by G-expectation introduced by Peng (cf. http://arxiv.org/PS_cache/math/pdf/0601/

0601035v2.pdf) in 2006. We show that the G-capacity can not be dynamic, and also demonstrate the relationship between symmetric G-martingale and the martingale under linear expectation. Based on these results and path-wise analysis, we obtain the martingale characterization the-orem for G Brownian motion without Markovian assumption. This thethe-orem covers the Lèvy’s martingale characterization theorem for Brownian motion, and it also gives a different method to prove Lèvy’s theorem.

Key words:G-Brownian motion, G-expectation, Martingale characterization, Capacity. AMS 2000 Subject Classification:Primary 60H05, 60H10.

Submitted to EJP on January 3, 2010, final version accepted November 9, 2010.

Supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 10901168), Natural Science Foundation Project of CQ CSTC (Grant No. 2009BB2039) and the Project of Chinese Ministry of Education (Grant No. 09YJCZH122).

Corresponding Author. Supported by NNSFC(Grant No. 10771214 and 71071155), MOE Humanities Social Science

Key Research Institute in University Foundation (Grant No. 07JJD910244), Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities, and Research Funds of Renmin University of China (Grant No.10XNL007)


(2)

1

I

NTRODUCTION

In 1969, Robert C. Merton introduced stochastic calculus to finance, see [20], and indeed to the

broader field of economics, beginning an amazing decade of developments. The most famous pricing

formula for the European call option was given by Black and Scholes in 1973, see[2]. As these

developments unfolded, Cox and Ross [6] notice that, without loss of generality, to price some

derivative security as an option, one would get the correct result by assuming that all of the securities have the same expected rate of return. This is the “risk neutral” pricing method. This notion is first

given by Harrison and Kreps[14], who formalize (under conditions) the near equivalence of the

absence arbitrage with the existence of some new “risk neutral” probability measure under which all expected rates of return are indeed equal to the current risk free rate. To get this “risk-neutral" probability measure, Harrison and Kreps apply Girsanov’s theorem to change the measure.

Black & Scholes’s result and Cox’s result have been widely used since it appeared. But their work deeply depends on certain assumptions, e.g., the interest rate and the volatility of the stock price remain constant and known. In fact, the interest rate and the volatility of the stock price are not always constant and known, which are called mean uncertainty and volatility uncertainty. As for the mean uncertainty, Girsanov’s theorem or Peng’s g-expectation is a powerful tool to solve the

problem, see[3]and [11]. How to deal with the volatility uncertainty is a big problem, see[1],

[15], [19], [27]. As in [9], the main difficulty is that we have to deal with a series of probability

measures which are not absolutely continuous with respect to one single probability measure. It shows that this problem can not be solved in a given probability space.

In 2006, Peng made a change to the heat equation that Brownian motion satisfies, see[23],[24],

and constructed the G-normal distribution via the modified heat equation. With this G-normal dis-tribution, a nonlinear expectation is given which is called G-expectation and the related conditional expectation is constructed, which is a kind of dynamic coherent risk measure introduced by Delbaen

in[7]. Under this framework, the canonical process is a G-Brownian motion. The stochastic calculus

of Itô’s type with respect to the G-Brownian motion and the related Itô’s formula are also derived. G-Brownian motion, different from Brownian motion in the classical case, is not defined on a given probability space.

It is interesting to get a pricing formula (Black-Scholes formula) in G-framework. To do this, it is important to give the Girsanov theorem in this framework. Its proof depends heavily on the martingale characterization of Brownian motion, due to Lèvy. This theorem enables us to recognize a Brownian motion just with one or two martingale properties of a process.

In order to get the Girsanov theorem, we need to describe this G-Brownian motion by its martingale properties. That is the martingale characterization theorem for G-Brownian motion.

In [29], the authors give the martingale characterization theorem for G-Brownian motion under

Markovian condition, but this condition is not so convenient in applications.

In this paper, we define capacity via G-expectation, and state that G-expectation is not filtration consistent. Then we investigate the relationship between symmetric G-martingales and martingales under linear expectation, when the corresponding G-heat equation is uniformly parabolic. Based on these results, we give the martingale characterization theorem for G-Brownian motion without

Markovian condition which improves the related result in [29]. The current result extends the

classical Lèvy’s theorem. Additionally, we give a different method to prove Lèvy’s theorem.


(3)

give the martingale characterization of G-Brownian motion when the corresponding G-heat equation is uniformly parabolic, see in section 5. G-expectation theory has received more attention since

Peng’s basic paper appeared, see[23],[24],[25]. Soner et al[21]study the G-martingale problem

under some condition, and investigate the representation theorem for all G-martingales including the non-symmetric martingale based on a class of backward stochastic differential equations. In the current work, we are focused on symmetric G-martingale, our method is totally different from

the method in[21]. As for the martingale characterization for G-Brownian motion, our method is

different from [29], which is based on viscosity solution theory for nonlinear parabolic equation.

But in this paper, the path wise analysis is important to underly our result, which is a different

approach from [29]. Meanwhile, the result in this paper is very useful for further application in

finance, especially for option pricing problems with volatility uncertainty. By using the result in this paper, we can prove the Girsanov type theorem under G-framework and the pricing formula. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we review the G-framework established

in [23] and adapt it according to our objective. In section 3, we investigate some properties of

G-expectation by using stochastic control, define the capacity via G-expectation, and show that it is not filtration consistent. In section 4, we investigate the relation between the symmetric

G-martingale and the G-martingale under each probability measure Pv, when the corresponding G-heat

equation is uniformly parabolic. In section 5, based on path wise analysis, we give the martingale characterization for G-Brownian motion. The last section is conclusion and discussion about this work and future work.

2

G-F

RAMEWORK

In this section, we recall the G-framework established in[23]. Let Ω =C0(R+) be the space of all

R-valued continuous paths functions(ωt)tR+, withω0=0. For anyω1,ω2∈Ω, we define

ρ(ω1,ω2):=

X

i=1

2−i[(max

t∈[0,i]|ω

1 tω

2 t|)∧1].

We set, for eacht[0,),

Wt := {η·∧t :η∈Ω},

Ft := Bt(W) =B(Wt),

Ft+ := Bt+(W) =

\

s>t

Bs(W),

F := _

s>0 Fs.

Then(Ω,F)is the canonical space with the natural filtration.

This space is used throughout the rest of this paper. For each T >0, consider the following spaces

of ˛aˇrrandom variables ˛a´s

L0i p(FT):=¦X=ϕ(ωt1,ωt2ωt1,· · ·,ωtmωtm

−1),∀m≥1,t1,· · ·,tm∈[0,T],∀ϕl i p(R

m)©,


(4)

Obviously, it holds that L0i p(Ft) Li p0(FT), for any t T < ∞. We notice that X,Y L0i p(Ft) meansX YL0i p(Ft)and|X| ∈L0i p(Ft). We further denote

L0i p(F):=

[

n=1

L0i p(Fn).

We setBt(ω) =ωt, and define

EG[ϕ(Bt+x)] =u(t,x),

whereu(t,x)is the viscosity solution to the following G-heat equation

  

∂u ∂tG(

2u ∂x2) =0, u(0,x) =ϕ(x).

ϕ(·)l i p(R),G(a) = 1

2σ2sup

0≤σ2≤1

2,σ0∈[0, 1].

For anyX(ω) =ϕ(Bt1,Bt2−Bt1,· · ·,BtmBtm−1)∈L

0

i p(F), 0<t1<· · ·<tm<∞, EG[ϕ(Bt

1,Bt2−Bt1,· · ·,BtmBtm−1)] =ϕm,

whereϕm is obtained via the backward deduction:

ϕ1(x1,· · ·,xm−1) =EG[ϕ(x1,· · ·,xm−1,BtmBtm−1)], ϕ2(x1,· · ·,xm−2) =EG[ϕ1(x1,· · ·,xm−2,Btm−1−Btm−2)],

.. .

ϕm−1(x1) =EG[ϕm−2(x1,Bt2−Bt1)], ϕm=EG[ϕm1(Bt1)].

And

EG[X|Ftj] =ϕmj(Bt1,Bt2−Bt1,· · ·BtjBtj−1).

Definition 2.1. The expectation EG[·], introduced through the above procedure is called G-expectation. The corresponding canonical process B is called a G-Brownian motion under EG[·].

Remark 2.2. As in[23], the G-expectation satisfies

(a) Monotonicity: EG[Y]≥EG[Y′], if YY, Y,Y′∈L0i p(F).

(b) Self dominated property: EG[X]EG[Y]EG[X Y], X,Y L0i p(F). (c) Positive homogeneity EG[λY] =λEG[Y]≥0, Y L0i p(F).

(d) Constant translatability EG[X+c] =EG[X] +c, XL0i p(F), c is a constant. Besides(a)s(d), the conditional G-expectation still satisfies the properties:


(5)

(e) Time consistency EG[EG[X|Ft]|Fs] =EG[X|Fts], XLi p0(F).

(f) EG[X Y|Fs] =X+EG[Y|Fs] +XEG[Y|Fs], X Li p0(Fs), Y L0i p(F). (g) EG[X+Y|Fs] =X+EG[Y|Fs], X L0i p(Fs), Y L0i p(F).

Remark 2.3. By properties(c)and(d), EG[·]satisfies EG[c] =c where c is a constant.

Remark 2.4. By theory of stochastic control as in[30], we know that, for any fixed T >0,

EG[X] = sup

v·∈Λ′ E

 ϕ

Z t2

t1

vsd Bs,· · ·,

Z tm

tm−1

vsd Bs

! = sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[X], (2.1)

where X = ϕ(ωt1,· · ·,ωtmωtm−1) ∈ L

0

i p(FT), E is the linear expectation under weiner measure, and G-expectation becomes linear expectation whenσ0=1,{Bt}t≥0is Brownian motion under Weiner

measure. Z

· 0

vd Bs(·):C[0,T]−→C[0,T]. Here

Λ′ = {v,v is progressively measurable and quadratic integrable s.t.,

σ20v2(t)1,a.s. with respect to Weiner measure, 0tT}, Λ = {Pv :Pv is the distribution of

Z ·

0

vsd Bs,v·∈Λ′}.

Lemma 2.5. For any X L0i p(F), if EG[|X|] =0, then for anyω∈Ω, we have X(ω) =0.

Proof: X =ϕ(ωt), EG[X] =supvΛE[|ϕ(

Z t 0

vsd Bs)|] =0. Let v ≡1, then E[|ϕ(Bt)|] =0. Since

ϕ(·) is Lipschitz continuous, then ϕ(·) 0. Similarly, we can prove that for any X L0i p(F)

satisfyingEG[|X|] =0, we haveX(ω) =0,∀ω∈Ω.

Remark 2.6. DenotekXk=EG[|X|],∀XL0i p(F). By Lemma 2.5, we can prove that(L 0

i p(F),k · k)is a normed space. Let(L1G(F),k · k)be the completion of(L0i p(F),k · k), then G-expectation and related conditional expectation can be continuously extended to the Banach space-(L1G(F),k · k). G-expectation satisfies properties (a) (d), and conditional G-expectation satisfies properties (a) (g). In the completion space, property(f)holds for any bounded random variable X , but we have EG[X Y|Fs] = X EG[Y],Y L1G(FsT),X L1G(Fs), and X 0. Similarly, we can definekXkp=E1/p[|X|p],p1. Let LGp(F)be the completion space of L0i p(F)under normk · kp. Obviously L

p

G(F)⊂ L p

G(F)for any

1pp, and it holds for any LGp(Ft)(the proof can be found in[23]).

Definition 2.7. X,Y LGp(FT), X Y in LGp, if EG[((XY)+)p] =0, p1.


(6)

Forp1 and 0<T<∞( fixed T). Consider the following type of simple processes

MGp,0(0,T) = {η:ηt(ω) = NX−1

j=0

ξtj(ω)I[tj,tj+1)(t),

N1, 0=t0<· · ·<tN=T, ξtj(ω)∈L

p

G(Ftj), j=0.· · ·,N−1}.

For eachηt(ω) =

PN−1

j=0 ξtj(ω)I[tj,tj+1)(t)∈M

p,0

G (0,T), the related Bochner’s integral is defined as

Z T 0

ηt(ω)d t= NX−1

j=0

ξtj(ω)(tj+1−tj), and

e

EG[η] = 1

T

Z T 0

EG[ηt]d t=

1

T NX−1

j=0

EG[ξtj(ω)](tj+1−tj).

We can easily check thatEeG[·]:MG1,0(0,T)Rsatisfies(a)(d)in Section 2.

kηkp= (

1

T

Z T 0

kηptkd t)1/p=

  T1

NX−1 j=0

EG[|ξtj(ω)|

p](t

j+1−tj)

  

1/p

.

As discussed in Remark 2.6, k · kp forms a norm inM

p,0

G (0,T). LetM p

G(0,T)be the completion of

MGp,0(0,T)under this norm.

3

C

APACITY

U

NDER

G-F

RAMEWORK

3.1

G-Expectation and Related Properties

G-expectation is a kind of time consistent nonlinear expectations, which has the properties of linear expectation in Weiner space except linearity. In this section, we prove some fundamental properties of G-expectation.

We set

Sp={M|M:R+×R,M(t,ω)LGp(Ft),T >0, {Mt}t[0,T]MGp(0,T)}.

First we will prove that an important class of random variable-bounded continuous functions belongs

to the completion space-L1G(F)

Remark 3.1. If XL1G(FT), there is a sequence fnLi p0(FT), such that fnconverges to f in L1G(FT), then for each PvΛ, fnconverges to f in L1(Ω,Pv), and this convergence is uniform with respect to Pv. We have EG[f] =supPv∈ΛEPv[f](see Proposition 2.2 in[9]).


(7)

Lemma 3.2. Λis tight, that is, for anyǫ >0, there exists a compact set KC([0,T]), such that for any Pv∈Λ, Pv(Kc)< ǫ, where Kcis the complement of K.

Proof: For any continuous functionx(t), t∈[0,T], define

ωx(δ) = sup

|st|≤δ,s,t∈[0,T]|

xtxs|.

By Arzela-Ascoli theorem and Prokhrov theorem (see Theorem 4.4.11 in[4]), to prove the tightness

ofΛ, we only need to prove that for anyα >0, for anyPvΛ, we have lim

δ→0Pv {x :ωx(δ)≥α}

=0. Forα >0, by Proposition 7.2 in the Appendix we know that

lim

δ→0Pv {x :ωx(δ)≥α}

≤ lim

δ→0 EP

v[ω

2 x(δ)]

α2 =0,

thenΛis tight.

Remark 3.3. For any fixed T, C[0,T]is a polish space, by Prokhrov theorem, we know thatΛis weakly compact. For XnL0i p(FT), Xn0pointwise. As in the Appendix of[9], by Dinni lemma, EG[Xn]0.

Lemma 3.4. For any fixed T>0,0<t<T , f Cb(Wt), we have f LG1(Ft).

Proof: For any bounded continuous f Cb(Wt), |f| ≤M, M>0, there exists a sequence of random

variables fnL0i p(Ft), such thatfnmonotonically converges to f.

AsΛis tight, for anyǫ >0, there exists a compact setK∈ FT, such that

sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[IKc]< ǫ,

whereKcis the complement ofK. Since a compact set is closed in any metric space, we know that

Kcis an open set, hence

EG[IKc] =sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[IKc]< ǫ.

And by Dini’s theorem on any compact setK, fnconverges to f uniformly,

lim

n→∞EG[|fnf|]≤nlim→∞[EG[|fnf|IK] +EG[|fnf|IKc]]≤,

then limn→∞EG[|fnf|] =0, note that this convergence is uniform with respect to t, sofL1G(FT).

3.2

Capacity under G-Framework

Since the publication of Kolomogrov’s famous book on probability, the study of “the nonlinear

prob-ability" theory named “capacity" has been studied intensively in the past decades, see [5], [8],

[12], [16], [18],[22],[26]. Hence it is meaningful to extend such a theory to G-framework, and

this section contributes to such an extension. We shall now define a nonlinear measure through G-expectation and investigate its properties.


(8)

Definition 3.5. PG(A) = supPv∈ΛPv(A), for any Borel set A, where Pv is the distribution of

Z t 0

vd Bs and v is a bounded adapted process, andΛis the collection of all such Pv.

By Remark 3.1 and Remark 3.3, PG is a regular Choquet capacity (we call it G-capacity), that is, it

has the following properties:

(1) For any Borel setA, 0PG(A)1;

(2) IfAB, then PG(A)PG(B);

(3) IfAn is a sequence of Borel sets, thenPG(

S

nAn)≤

P

nPG(An);

(4) IfAn is an increasing sequence of Borel sets, then

PG([

n

An) =lim

n PG(An).

Remark 3.6. Here property (4) dose not hold for the intersection of decreasing sets. There are two ways to define capacity under G framework, see[10].

LetΛebe the closure ofΛunder weak topology. (1) PG(A) =supPv∈ΛPv(A),

(2) PG(A) =supPΛePv(A).

Then PGand PGall satisfy the properties in Remark 3.2.

We use the standard capacity related vocabulary: A set A is polar if PG(A) =0, a property holds ˛ aˇrquasi-surely ˛a´s (q.s.), if it holds outside a polar set. Here PGquasi-surely is equivalent to PGquasi-surely. Even in general, PG(A)≤ PG(A), but if PG(A) =0, IAL1G(FT). Then by Theorem 59 in [10](page 24), PG(A) =PG(A) =0. Thus, a property holds PG-quasi-surely if and only if it holds PG-quasi-surely.

Remark 3.7. As in the Appendix of [9], we consider the Lebesgue extension of G-expectation, we can define G-expectation for a large class of measurable functions, such as all the functions with

supP

v∈ΛEPv[|X|] <, but we can not define G conditional expectation. So far we can only define

G conditional expectation for the random variables in L1G(F), in the rest of the paper, we denote

supP

v∈ΛEPv[X] =EG[X], but that dose not mean XL

1 G(F).

First we give the property of this Choquet capacity-PG:

Proposition 3.8. Let p1.

(1) If A is a polar set, then for anyξLpG(FT), EG[IAξ] =0. (2) PG{|ξ|>a} ≤ EG[|ξ|

p] ap L

p

G(FT), a>0.

(3) If Xn, X LGp(F), EG[|XnXp|p]0, then there exists a sub-sequence Xn

k of Xn, such that


(9)

Proof: (1)Without loss of generality, let p=1. IfξL0i p(FT), then EG[IAξ] =0. IfξL1G(FT),

then there exists a sequence of random variables ξn, which satisfies EG[|ξnξ|] −→ 0, and

EG[|ξnIAξIA|]−→0, hence we obtain

EG[ξIA] = lim

n→∞EG[ξnIA] =0.

(2) From

EG[|ξ|p] =EG[|ξ|pI{|ξ|>a}+|ξ|pI{|ξ|≤a}]≥apPG{|ξ|>a},

we get the result.

(3) By (2), we know that for anyǫ >0,

lim

n→∞PG{|XnX|> ǫ}=0.

Then for every positive integer k, there existsnk>0, such that

PG{|XnX| ≥ 1

2k}< 1

2k, ∀nnk.

Supposen1<n2<. . .<nk<. . ., letXk=Xnk be a sub-sequence ofXn. Then

PG{Xk9X}=PG

( [

m

\

k

[

v

|Xk+vX| ≥ǫm

)

≤ X

m PG

( \

k

[

v

|Xk+vX| ≥ǫm

)

≤ X

m PG

( [

v

|Xk

0+m+vX| ≥ǫm

)

≤ X

m

X

v PG

|Xk

0+m+vX| ≥

1 2k0+m+v

≤ X

m

X

v

1 2k0+m+v

= 1

2k0 →0.

Therefore,PG{Xk9X}=0.

Next we investigate the relation betweenX Y in LGp, andXY, q.s.

Lemma 3.9. EG[(XY)+] =0if and only if XY , q.s.

Proof: Without loss of generality, suppose thatp=1, ifXY, q.s.,{XY ≥0}is a polar set. Then by Proposition 3.8, we know that

EG[(XY)+] =EG[(XY)I{XY0}] =0.

IfX Y inL1G, which means EG[(XY)+] =0, then by Proposition 3.8, for anyǫ >0, we have

PG[(XY)+> ǫ]≤

EG[(XY)+]


(10)

Letǫ↓0, forPGis a Choquet capacity, we know

PG[(XY)+>0] =lim

ǫ→0PG[(XY)

+> ǫ] =0,

so we havePG[X Y] =PG[(XY)+>0] =0, that isX Y q.s.

Remark 3.10. After defining the capacity, one important issue is whether IALG1(F), for any Borel set A∈ F. Here we give a counter example that there exists a sequence of Borel sets which do not belong to L1G(F).

Example 3.11. Let

An=

 

ω: limt→0

Bt+sBs

p

2tlog log 1/t

(11/2n, 1)

 

, n=1, 2,· · ·

Then Anφ, for any fixed n, let v1 1

3n, Ôò

Pv(An) =P

 

ω:(1−

1

3n)limt→0

Bt+sBs

p

2tlog log 1/t

(11/2n, 1)

  =1,

which meanslimn→∞PG(An) =1.

For any sequences of random variables{Xn} ⊂ L1G(F), satisfying Xn ↓0 q.s., we have EG[Xn]0,

see Theorem 26 in[10]. So the setsAndo not belong to L1G(F).

Actually, the next lemma tells us even not all the open Borel sets belong toL1G(F).

Lemma 3.12. There exists an open set A∈ FT, such that IAdose not belongs to L1G(FT).

Proof: We prove this result by contradiction. If for any open setA∈ FT, IA L1G(FT) holds. For

all the open sets satisfyingAnφ, we have PG(An) ↓0. Because for any Borel setB, there exists

compact sets{Fn} ⊂B satisfyingPG(B\Fn)0, see[16]. Then we have for any Borel setB∈ FT,

IB LG1(FT). But Example 3.11 shows that not all the Borel sets belong to L1G(FT), which is a contradiction.

Then we can not define conditional G-expectation for IA, where Ais any Borel set, and even for

any open set, that means we can not define conditional G-capacity, and that is why we claim that G-expectation is not filtration consistent.

4

S

YMMETRIC

M

ARTINGALE IN

G-F

RAMEWORK

We begin with the definition of martingale in G-framework.

Definition 4.1. M ∈ S2 is called a martingale, if for any0≤ st < ∞, it satisfies E[Mt|Fs] = Ms; if furthermore M is symmetric, that is E[Mt|Fs] =E[Mt|Fs], then it is called a symmetric martingale.

In this section, when the corresponding G-heat equation is uniformly parabolic, which meansσ0>

0, we prove that the symmetric martingale is a martingale under each probability measurePv, and


(11)

4.1

Path analysis

In this section, we give some path properties of quadratic variation process Bt and the related

stochastic integral

Z t 0

η(s)d Bs,ηMG2(0,T)and

Z t 0

η1(s)dBs,η1(s)∈MG1(0,T).

From the definition of EG[·], we know that the canonical processBt is a quadratic integrable

mar-tingale under eachPv. So they have a universal version of “quadratic variation process ofBt", and

by the definition of stochastic integral with respect to G-Brownian motion, for any ηMG2(0,T),

Z T 0

ηsd Bs is well defined, which means

Z T 0

ηsd Bs is aPv local martingale. Similar arguments can

be found in Lemma 2.10 in [10]. Then, due to the Doob’s martingale inequality for each Pv, the

following result holds.

Lemma 4.2. For anyηMG2(0,T),

Z t 0

η(s)d Bs is quasi-sure continuous.

Proof:IfηMG2,0(0,T), then the result is true. IfηMG2(0,T), then there exist{ηn} ⊂MG2,0(0,T)

such that

Z T 0

EG[|η(s)−ηn(s)|2]ds−→0.

For we have

sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[ sup

0≤tT|

Z t 0

(ηηn)d Bs|2]Ksup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[

Z T 0

(ηηn)2dBs]

K sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[

Z T 0

(ηηn)2ds]≤K

Z T 0

sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[(ηηn)

2]ds −→0.

Hence,

Z t 0

ηn(s)d Bs uniformly converges to

Z t 0

η(s)d Bs q.s. Therefore,

Z t 0

η(s)d Bs is continuous

q.s.

By similar argument we can get the following lemma.

Lemma 4.3. For anyηMG1(0,T),

Z t 0

η(s)dBs and

Z t 0

η(s)ds are quasi-surely continuous.

4.2

Representation theorem

In this section, we are concerned with the G-martingale when the corresponding G-heat equation

is uniformly parabolic (σ0 > 0). In the following, for any XL0i p(FT), we will give X a

repre-sentation in terms of stochastic integral. For this part, Peng gives the conjecture for reprerepre-sentation

theorem of G-martingales. Soner et al[21]prove this theorem for a large class of G-martingales by

BSDE method. Here for the ease of exposition, we prove the theorem separately for some special martingales.


(12)

Lemma 4.4. Supposeσ0>0, if u is the solution of G-heat equation, then we have

u(r,Btr) =u(t, 0) +

Z tr

0

ux(Bv)d Bv+

Z tr

0

ux x(Bv)dBv

Z tr

0

(u+x xσ20ux x)d v.

Proof:The proof follows that of Itô’s formula. Due to the regularity of parabolic equation, see[18],

we knowu,ux,ux x are all uniformly continuous. Since Lipschitz continuous functions are dense in

uniform continuous functions, we assume thatu,ux,ux x are Lipschitz continuous.

Letδn=

tr

n , we have

u(r,Btr)u(t, 0) =

n−1

X

k=0

”

u(t(k+1)δn,B(k+1)δn)−u(tkδn,Bkδn)

—

=

n−1

X

k=0

”

u(t−(k+1)δn,B(k+1)δn)−u(tkδn,B(k+1)δn)

—

+

n−1

X

k=0

”

u(tkδn,B(k+1)δn)−u(tkδn,Bkδn)

—

=

n−1

X

k=0

”

ut(tkδn,Bkδn)δn+ux(tkδn,Bkδn)(B(k+1)δnBkδn) +1

2ux x(tkδn,Bkδn)(B(k+1)δnBkδn)

2

ξn+ηn,

where

ηn =

1 2

n−1

X

k=0

[ux x(tkδn,Bkδn+θ1(B(k+1)δnBkδn))−ux x(tkδn,Bkδn)](B(k+1)δnBkδn)

2,

ξn = n−1

X

k=0

”

ut(tkδn+θ2δn,B(k+1)δn)−ut(tkδn,B(k+1)δn)

—

δn,

+

n−1

X

k=0

”

ut(tkδn,B(k+1)δn)−ut(tkδn,Bkδn)

—

δn,

andθ1,θ2are constants in[0, 1], which depend onω, tandn. Hence,

EG[|ηn|]

n−1

X

k=0

EG”|ux x(tn,Bkδn+θ(B(k+1)δnBkδn))

ux x(tkδn,Bkδn)|(B(k+1)δnBkδn)

2— ≤ K

n−1

X

k=0

EG[|B(k+1)δ

nBkδn|

3]K

n−1

X

k=0

δ3/2n −→0.


(13)

Then, we have

EG[| n

X

k=1

ut(tkδn,Bkδn)I[kδn,(k+1)δn)(v)−ut(tv,Bv)|]≤C(δn+δ

1/2

n )−→0.

Therefore,

n−1

X

k=0

ut(tkδn,Bkδn)δn−→

Z tr

0

ut(tv,Bv)d v. Similarly we get

n−1

X

k=0

ux(tkδn,Bkδn)(B(k+1)δnBkδn)−→

Z tr

0

ux(tv,Bv)d Bv. Note

EG[|

n−1

X

k=0

ux x(tkδn,Bkδn)(B(k+1)δnBkδn)2− n−1

X

k=0

ux x(tkδn,Bkδn)(〈B〉(k+1)δn− 〈Bn)|2]

n−1

X

k=0

EG[|ux x(tkδn,Bkδn)|

2

|(B(k+1)δ

nBkδn)

2

−(B(k+1)δ

n− 〈Bkδn)|

2]

+ 2X

j6=i

EG[ux x(tjδn,Bjδn)ux x(tiδn,Biδn)((B(j+1)δnBjδn)

2

−(B(j+1)δn− 〈Bjδn)) ((B(i+1)δnBiδn)

2

−(B〉(i+1)δn− 〈Biδn))]

n−1

X

k=0

EG[(c+c|Bkδn|

2) |

Z (k+1)δn

kδn

(BvBkδn)d Bv|

2]

n−1

X

k=0 C EG[|

Z (k+1)δn

kδn

(BvBkδn)d Bv|

2]C

n−1

X

k=0

δ2n−→0, and

n−1

X

k=0

ux x(tkδn,Bkδn)(〈B〉(k+1)δn− 〈Bkδn)−→

Z tr

0

ux x(tv,Bv)dBv.

Sinceusolves G-heat equation, we get

u(r,Btr)u(t, 0) =

Z tr

0

ut(tv,Bv)d v+

Z tr

0

ux(tv,Bv)d Bv

+

Z tr

0

ux x(tv,Bv)dBv

=

Z tr

0

ux(tv,Bv)d Bv+

Z tr

0

ux x(tv,Bv)dBv

−1

2

Z tr

0


(14)

Theorem 4.5. Whenσ0>0, then for any XLi p0(FT), we have

X =EG[|ϕ(·)|] +

Z tm

0

Zsd Bs+

Z tm

0

η(s)dBs

Z tm

0

(η+−σ20η−)ds.

Proof:Whenm=1, for the regularity of theu, limr0u(r,Btr(ω)) =ϕ(Bt(ω)). By Lemma 4.4, and path analysis in Section 3, we know

ϕ(Bt) = u(t, 0) +

Z t 0

ux(tv,Bv)d Bv

+

Z t 0

ux x(tv,Bv)dBv

Z t 0

(u+x xσ20ux x)d v.

Due to the definition of G-expectation,EG[ϕ(Bt)] =u(t, 0), so the result holds whenm=1.

By similar argument, we get

ϕ(BTBt) = u(Tt, 0) +

Z T t

ux(Tv,BvBt)d Bv

+

Z T t

ux x(Tv,BvBt)dBv

Z T t

(u+x xσ20ux x)d v.

Whenm=2, for each x

ϕ(x,BTBt) = u(Tt,x, 0) +

Z T t

uy(Tv,x,BvBt)d Bv

+

Z T t

uy y(Tv,x,BvBt)dBv

Z T t

(u+y y(Tv,x,BvBt)−σ20uy y(Tv,x,BvBt))d v.

By continuous dependence estimate theorem in [13], we know for each fixed t, u(T t,x, 0) is

lipschitz continuous and bounded with respect tox, then there existηMG1(0,T)andzMG2(0,T),

such that

u(Tt,Bt, 0) =EG[|u(Tt,Bt, 0)|] +

Z t 0

zsd Bs+

Z t 0

ηsdBs

Z t 0

(η+sσ20ηs )ds. (4.2)

That is

ϕ(Bt,BT Bt) =EG[ϕ(Bt,BT Bt)] +

Z T 0

zsd Bs+

Z T 0

ηsdBs

Z T 0

(η+sσ20ηs )ds.

Hereηandzare different from (4.2).


(15)

4.3

Properties for the Symmetric Martingale

From[23], we know EG[(Btt)+] =EG[(σ20t− 〈Bt)+] =0. Thenσ20t ≤ 〈Bt t, andσ20(T

t)≤ 〈BT − 〈Bt Tt, for anyt T.

Lemma 4.6. For anyηMG1(0,T), we have

Z T 0

η+(s)dBs

Z T 0

η+(s)ds≤0q.s.,and

Z T 0

η−(s)dBsσ02

Z T 0

η−(s)ds≥0.

Proof:IfηMG1,0(0,T), then

Z T 0

η+(s)dBs= n−1

X

j=0

ξ+j(Btj+1− 〈Btj)≤

n−1

X

j=0

ξ+j(tj+1−tj) =

Z T 0

η+(s)ds,

and Z

T

0

η−(s)dBs=

n−1

X

j=0

ξj (Bt

j+1− 〈Btj)≥σ

2 0

n−1

X

j=0

ξ+j(tj+1tj) =σ20

Z T 0

η−(s)ds.

IfηMG1(0,T), then there existsηnMG1,0(0,T), such that

EG

 

Z T 0

(ηnη)dBs

−→ 0,

EG

 

Z T 0

(ηnη)ds

−→ 0.

Then there exists a subsequenceηkηn such that

Z T 0

(ηkη)dBs−→0, q.s.,

and Z

T

0

(ηkη)ds−→0, q.s..

Therefore

Z T 0

η+(s)dBs

Z T 0

η+(s)ds ≤ 0, q.s.

Z T 0

η−(s)dBsσ02

Z T 0

η−(s)ds 0, q.s.

Theorem 4.7. Supposeσ0>0, then for any XL1G(FT)=EG[X | Ft]satisfies

sup

Pv∈Λ


(16)

Proof:IfX L0i p(FT), then

XT =EG[XT] +

Z T 0

zsd Bs+

Z T 0

ηsdBs

Z T 0

(η+−σ02η−)ds.

By Theorem 4.1.42 in[24], we have

η=EG[XT | Ft] =EG[XT] +

Z t 0

zsd Bs+

Z t 0

ηsdBs

Z t 0

(η+−σ20η−)ds.

Since

Z t 0

zsd Bs is a quadratic integrable martingale for eachPv, then

sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[(Xη)IA] = sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv

 (

Z T t

ηsdBs

Z T t

(η+−σ20η−)ds+

Z T t

zsd Bs)IA

 

= sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv

 (

Z T t

ηsdBs

Z T t

(η+−σ20η−)ds)IA

 0. On the other hand

sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv

 (

Z T t

ηsdBs

Z T t

(η+−σ20η−)ds)IA

  sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv

 

Z T t

ηsdBs

Z T t

(η+−σ20η−)ds

 =0.

Therefore supP

v∈ΛEPv[(Xη)IA] =0.

IfX LG1(FT), then there exist XnL0i p(FT), such thatEG[|XXn|]0 and

EG[|EG[X | Ft]EG[Xn| Ft]|]0. Hence,

sup

Pv∈Λ

EP

v[(XEG[X | Ft])IA] = sup

Pv∈Λ

EP

v[(XXn+EG[Xn| Ft]−EG[X | Ft])IA + (XnEG[Xn| Ft])IA]

EG[|XXn|] +EG[|EG[X | Ft]EG[Xn| Ft]|]

+ sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[(XnEG[Xn| Ft])IA]−→0. On the other hand

sup

Pv∈Λ

EPv[(XEG[X | Ft])IA] ≥ sup Pv∈Λ

EPv[(XnEG[Xn| Ft])IA]

EG[|XXn|]EG[|EG[X| Ft]−EG[Xn| Ft]|]−→0.

So supP

v∈ΛEPv[(XEG[X| Ft])IA] =0.

The next corollary states that there is a universal version of the conditional expectation for the


(17)

Corollary 4.8. Ifσ0>0, MTLG1(FT), andEG[MT | Ft] =EG[−MT | Ft], then EG[MT | Ft] =EPv[MT | Ft], Pv.a.s.

Then consequently we have the main result of this section.

Theorem 4.9. If M is a symmetric martingale under G expectation withσ0>0, then M is a martingale under each Pv.

Remark 4.10. We can not hope that

EPv[X|Ft]EG[X|Ft] =EG[X|Ft]≤ −EPv[X|Ft] =EPv[X|Ft]

Obviously for any XL1G(F), EG[X]≥ EPv[X]. But this is not trivial for conditional G expectation,

since it is defined as the “Markovian" version, so EP

v[X|Ft]≤EG[X|Ft]does not hold for each Pv. As a corollary, we can get the Doob’s Martingale inequality for “symmetric G-martingale".

Corollary 4.11. When σ0 > 0, ff MTL2G(FT), andEG[MT | Ft] = EG[−MT | Ft]and Mt is quasi-surely continuous then we have PG[sup0≤tT|Mt| ≥λ]≤

1

λpEG[|MT|

p], for any p

≥1, T ≥0, as a special case EG[sup0≤tT|Mt|2]≤2EG[|MT|2].

Proof: By the Doob’s martingale inequality in probability space, we have

PG[ sup

0≤tT|

Mt| ≥λ]

= sup

Pv∈Λ

Pv[ sup

0≤tT|

Mt| ≥λ]

≤ sup

Pv∈Λ 1

λpEPv[|MT|

p]

= 1

λpEG[|MT|p].

5

M

ARTINGALE

C

HARACTERIZATION OF

G-B

ROWNIAN

M

OTION

We are ready to prove the Martingale Characterization theorem for G-Brownian Motion.

Theorem 5.1. Let M ∈ S2. Suppose that (I) M is a symmetric martingale; (II) Mt2t is a martingale;

(III) forσ0>020tMt2 is a martingale; and


(18)

Then M is a G-Brownian motion in the sense that M has the same finite distribution as the G-Brownian motion B.

Remark 5.2. The Lèvy’s martingale characterization of Brownian motion in a probability space states that, Bt is a continuous martingale with respect to Ft, and B2tt is a Ft martingale, iff Bt is a Brownian motion. Our martingale characterization of G-Brownian motion covers Lèvy’s martingale characterization of Browninan motion, when σ0 = 1. In a probability space, the quadratic processBt of Brownian motion Bt almost sure equals to t with respect to the probability measure P. But in the G-framework, the quadratic processBt of G -Brownian motion Bt is not a fixed function any more. Instead, it is a stochastic process in G-framework. The criteria(I I I) is the description of the nonsymmetric property forBt. Condition (IV) is reasonable, thanks to [10], for any G-Brownian motion, it has continuous path.

In a probability space, thanks to the characteristic function of normal distribution, Lèvy’s martingale characteristic theorem of Brownian motion holds. But in G-framework, there is no characteristic

function of “G-normal distribution"(see the definition in[23]), we have to find a different method

to solve this problem.

Next we shall prove Theorem 5.1 in 4 steps.

Proof of Theorem 5.1:

Step 1. ηMG2(0,T), we define the stochastic integral of Itô’s type

Z T 0

ηd Mt, and prove that

Z t 0

ηd Msis a symmetric martingale underEG[·].

By conditions(I)(I V)in Theorem 5.1, we have the following proposition.

Proposition 5.3. for any tjtj+1<titi+1, (1) EG[(Mt

j+1−Mtj)ξtj(Mti+1−Mti)ξti] =0,ξtjL

p

G(Ftj),ξtiL

p G(Fti),

(2) EG[(Mt

j+1−Mtj)

2

|Ftj] =EG[(Mtj+1−Mtj)

2] =t

j+1−tj, (3) EG[X+ξtj(Mtj+1−Mtj)

2] =E

G[X+ξtj((Mtj+1)

2 −(Mt

j)

2)], X

LGp(FT),ξtjL

p G(Ftj).

Let

Z t 0

ηd Ms=

Z T 0

ηI[0,t](s)d Ms. The next lemma shows that

Z t 0

ηd Ms is a symmetric martingale.

Lemma 5.4. For anyηMG2(0,T),t[0,T],

Z t 0

ηd Ms is a symmetric martingale.

Step 2: The quadratic variation process Mt of Mt exists. Defining the stochastic integral with

respect to〈Mtin MG1(0,T), we can get the isometric formula in the G-framework.

Now we give the isometry formula in the G-framework. First, we give a proposition.


(19)

Proposition 5.5. For all0st,ξL1G(Fs)and X L1G(F)we have

EG[X+ξ(Mt2Ms2)] =EG[X+ξ(MtMs)2] =EG[X+ξ(Mt− 〈Ms)].

Lemma 5.6. ForηMG2(0,T), it holds that

EG[(

Z T 0

η(s)d Ms)2] =EG[

Z T 0

η2(s)dMs]

Z T 0

EG[η2(s)]ds.

Remark 5.7. We can prove Lemma 5.4 and 5.6 by the similar method to that in[23]and[29]. Thus we omit the proof.

Next, we investigate the property of the quadratic processMt.

Lemma 5.8. (1)

EG

 

‚Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv

Œ2

Fs

 =EG

–Z t s

(MvMs)2dMv

™

= 1

2(ts)

2.

(2) For anyηMG1(0,T), 1

2

Z t 0

ηsdMs

Z t 0

G(ηs)ds is a martingale.

Proof: (1) Lets=t0<t1<. . .<tN =t, andtj+1tj= ts

N . Note that

NX−1 j=0

(MtjMs)(Mtj+1−Mtj)−→

Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv in L2G(Ft).

Then

 

NX−1 j=0

(MtjMs)(Mtj+1Mtj)

   2 −→ ‚Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv

Œ2

in L1G.

And we have

EG     EG   Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv

Œ2

Fs

 EG

      

NX−1 j=0

(MtjMs)(Mtj+1−Mtj)

   2 Fs        

EG

   EG

    ‚Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv

Œ2 −

  

NX−1 j=0

(MtjMs)(Mtj+1Mtj)

   2 Fs        

= EG

    ‚Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv

Œ2 −

  

NX−1 j=0

(Mt

jMs)(Mtj+1−Mtj)

   2    −→0.


(20)

So EG       

NX−1 j=0

(MtjMs)(Mtj+1−Mtj)

   2 Fs   

−→EG

 

Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv

Œ2

Fs

  in L1G.

Now EG       

NX−1 j=0

(MtjMs)(Mtj+1−Mtj)

   2 Fs    

= EG

      

NX−1 j=0

(MtjMs)2(Mtj+1Mtj)

   2 Fs     =

NX−1 j=0

(tjs)(tj+1tj).

We know EG   Z t s

(MvMs)d Mv

Œ2

Fs

 = lim

N→∞

NX−1 j=0

(tjs)(tj+1tj) =

Z t s

vd v= 1 2(ts)

2.

(2) For any ηMG1,0(0,T), ηt =

PN−1

j=0 ξtj(ω)I[tj,tj+1)(t), for any t ∈[0,T], suppose t = tN−1.

Then, EG   Z T 0

ηsdMs−2

Z T 0

G(ηs)ds

Ft  

= EG

  

NX−1 j=0

ξj(〈Mtj+1− 〈Mtj)−2

NX−1 j=0

G(ξj)(tj+1−tj)

FtN−1

  

=

NX−2 j=0

ξj(〈Mtj+1− 〈Mtj)−2

NX−2 j=0

G(ξj)(tj+1−tj) +ξ+tN−1EG

•

MtN− 〈MtN−1

FtN−1

˜

+ξt

N−1EG

•

−(Mt

N− 〈MtN−1)

FtN−1

˜

−2G(ξN−1)(tNtN−1)

=

Z t 0

ηsdMs−2

Z t 0

G(ηs)ds+2G(ξN−1)(tNtN−1)−2G(ξN−1)(tNtN−1)

=

Z t 0

ηsdMs−2

Z t 0

G(ηs)ds.

IfηMG1(0,T), then there exists a sequenceηNMG1,0(0,T), such thatηN −→ηin MG1(0,T), and (ηN)+


(1)

and

u(t,Mt+δ)−u(s,Ms+δ) =

NX−1 j=0

h

u(tj+1,Mδ+t

j+1−)−u(tj,Mtj+1+δ)

+u(tj,+tj+1−)−u(tj,Mtj+δ)

i

=

NX−1 j=0

€

u(vj+1δ,Mv)−u(vjδ,Mv) Š

+

NX−1 j=0

ux(vjδ,Mvj)(Mvj+1−Mvj)

+1

2 NX−1

j=0

ux x(vjδ,Mvj)(Mvj+1−Mvj)

2

+ 1

2 NX−1

j=0

h

ux x(vjδ,Mv

j+θj(ω)(Mvj+1−Mvj))−ux x(vjδ,Mvj)

i (Mv

j+1−Mvj)

2

=

NX−1 j=0

Z vj+1

vj

ut(vδ,Mv

j+1−)d v+

NX−1 j=0

ux(vjδ,Mv

j)(Mvj+1−Mvj)

+1

2 N−X1

j=0

ux x(vjδ,Mvj)(Mvj+1−Mvj)

2+

1 2

NX−1 j=0

h

ux x(vjδ,Mvj+θj(ω)(Mvj+1−Mvj))−ux x(vjδ,Mvj)

i

(Mvj+1Mvj)2, whereθj(ω)∈(0, 1), vj=δ+tj.

Now that EG   

NX−1 j=0

Z vj+1

vj

ut(vδ,Mv

j)d v

Z t+δ

s+δ

ut(vδ,Mv)d v   

EG

  

NX−1 j=0

Z vj+1

vj

C|MvMv

j|d v

   ≤ NX−1

j=0 2

3|vj+1vj| 3/2=

NX−1 j=0

2 3δ

3/2 N −→0, and

NX−1 j=0

ux(vjδ,Mv

j)I[tj,tj+1)−→ux(vδ,Mv),

we have NX−1

ux(vjδ,Mv

j)(Mvj+1−Mvj)−→

Z t+δ


(2)

Since EG    

NX−1 j=0

ux x(vjδ,Mvj)(Mvj+1−Mvj)

2 −

NX−1 j=0

ux x(vjδ,Mvj)(〈M〉vj+1− 〈M〉vj+1) 2   

= EG

    N−1X j=0

ux x(vjδ,Mvj) Z vj+1

vj

(MvMvj)d Mv

2   

EG

  

NX−1 j=0

u2x x(vjδ,Mvj−Mδ)  

Z vj+1

vj

(MvMvj)d Mv

 

2

 +2EG

  

X

j6=i

ux x(vjδ,Mvj)

ux x(viδ,Mvi)

Z vj+1

vj

(MvMvj)d Mv

Z vi+1

vi

(MvMvi)d Mv

 

NX−1

j=0

EG[u2x x(vjδ,Mv

j)−

2 NC

NX−1 j=0

EG[1+δ+|Mv

j|]δ

2

N −→0, we have

NX−1 j=0

ux x(vjδ,Mvj)(〈M〉vj+1− 〈M〉vj)−→

Z t+δ

s+δ

ux x(vδ,Mv)dM〉v.

So the result holds.

Step 4.

Lemma 5.11. If u(t,x)is the viscosity solution to the G-heat equation, andσ0>0, then EG[ϕ(Mt+x)] =u(t,x), ϕl i p(R).

Proof: For 0< σ0≤1, then by Theorem 4.13 in[17],u(t,x)∈C1,2((0,TR), andu(t,x),ut(t,x) andux x(t,x)are all uniformly continuous,ux(t,x) is bounded and continuous, see in[28]. Then by Lemma 5.10, for any 0< ǫ <vT, we have

u(ǫ,+v−ǫ+x)−u(v,x) =

Z v−ǫ+δ δ

ut(v+δs,Ms+x)ds

+

Z v−ǫ+δ δ

ux(v+δs,Ms+x)d Ms+ 1 2

Z v−ǫ+δ δ


(3)

By Lemma 5.8, it is easy to check that

EG[u(ǫ,+v−ǫ+x)]−u(v,x)

= EG

 

Z vǫ+δ δ

ut(v+δs,MsMδ+x)ds

+ 1

2

Z vǫ+δ δ

ux x(v+δs,Ms+x)dM〉s  

= EG

 1

2

Z v−ǫ+δ δ

ux x(v+δs,Ms+x)dM〉s

Z vǫ+δ δ

G(ux x(v+δs,MsMδ+x))ds

 

= 0.

Then limǫ→0EG[u(ǫ,+v−ǫ+x)] =u(v,x).

We also have

EG[|u(ǫ,+v−ǫ+x)−u(0,+v−+x)]≤2C EG[ p

ǫ+|+v−ǫ+v|]≤4C

p

ǫ, whereC is the Lipschitz constant ofϕ.

ThenEG[ϕ(+t−+x)] =u(t,x) =EG[ϕ(Mt+x)].

Without loss of generality, by the definition of G-Brownian motion, see[23], we only need to prove the case form=2:

EG[ϕ(Mt1,Mt2−Mt1)]

= EG[EG[ϕ(Mt1,Mt2−Mt1)|Ft1]] = EG[EG[ϕ(x,Mt

2−Mt1)|Ft1]x=Mt1] = EG[EG[ϕ(x,Mt2t1)]x=M

t1].

Based on Step 1Step 4, M has the same finite distribution with G-Brownian motionB, we com-plete the proof of the Theorem 5.1.

6

D

ISCUSSION

In this paper, we investigate the properties of capacity defined by expectation, and prove that G-expectation is not filtration consistent. Meanwhile by path-wise analysis, we prove that symmetric G-martingales are martingales under eachPv. Based on these arguments, we obtain the martingale characterization theorem for a G-Brownian motion. The application of this framework in finance can be found in[9]. Our martingale characterization theorem of G-Brownian motion includes Lèvy’s martingale characterization theorem of Brownian motion. In the proof of classical Lèvy’s martingale characterization theorem, the characterization function of normal distribution plays an important


(4)

Our proof of martingale characterization of G-Brownian motion gives a totally different method to prove Lèvy’s martingale characterization of Brownian motion. In our proof the compactness ofΛis essential. Based on our result one can investigate some elementary problems such as the martingale representation with respect to G-Brownian motion in G-framework.

7

A

PPENDIX

Lemma 7.1. If ML1G(Ft),ϕ(x)is Lipschitz continuous, thenϕ(M(t))L1G(Ft).

Proof: Without loss of generality, supposeϕ(x)0. We know that there exists a sequenceϕn(x)∈ l i p(R) such thatϕn(x)−→ϕ(x)monotonically. By the Lipschitz continuous ofϕ(x), and the fact thatEG[|ϕ(Mt)|2]<, we have

EG[|ϕ(Mt)ϕn(Mt)|]EG[|ϕ(Mt)|I{|Mt|≥n}]

EG1/2[|ϕ(Mt)|2]EG1/2[I{|M

t|≥n}]≤E

1/2

G [|ϕ(Mt)|2]

EG1/2[Mt2]

n −→0.

Proposition 7.2. For any v ∈Λ′, set Iδ = E[sup|st|≤δ| Z t

s

vτd Bτ|], thenlimδ→0 =0, where E

refers to the expectation under Weiner measure, and B is the canonical process which is the Brownian motion under Weiner measure. (see the definition ofΛ′in §3 )

Proof:The proof is trivial, and hence omitted.

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the anonymous referee for carefully reading the

manuscript and offering useful suggestions and comments which improved the clarity of the paper. We would like to thank Professor Bingyi Jing from Hong Kong University of Science and Technology for his constructive advice. Some results of this work were carried out while Dr. Xu was visiting Shandong University and Southern California University. She would like to thank Professor Shige Peng, Professor Jin Ma and Professor Jianfeng Zhang for their hospitality, suggestions and helpful discussions which greatly improved the presentation.

References

[1] Avellaneda, M., Lèvy,A. and Paras, A. Pricing and Hedging Derivatives Securities in Markets with Uncertain Volatilities.Appl. Math. Finance2, 73-88(1995).

[2] Black, F., and Scholes, M. The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. The Journal of Political Economy81, 637-659(1973).

[3] Chen, Z. and Epstein, L. Ambiguity, Risk and Asset Returns in Continuous Time.Econometrica, 70:4, 1403-1443(2002). MR1929974


(5)

[4] Cheng, SH.Modern Probability. Peking Press, Beijing(2000).

[5] Choquet G. Theory of Capacities. Ann.Inst. Fourier 5,131-295(1955). MR0080760

[6] Cox, J. and Ross, S. The Valuation of Options for Alternative Stochastic Processes. Journal of Financial Economics3, 145-166(1976).

[7] Dealbaen, F. Coherent Risk Measures on General Probability Space. Advances in Finance and Stochastics, Springer-Verlag, pp.1-37(2002). MR1929369

[8] Dempster, A. P. Upper and Lower Probabilities Induced by Multi-Valued Mapping. Annals of Mathematical Statistics 38, 325-339(1967).) MR0207001

[9] Denis, Laurent., and Martini, C. A Theoretical Framework for the Pricing of Model Contin-gent Claims in the Presence of Model Uncertainty. Annals of Applied Probability,16:2, 827-852(2006). MR2244434

[10] Denis, L., Hu, MS., and Peng, S. Function spaces and capacity related to a sublinear expecta-tion: application G Brownian Motion Pathes. arXiv: 0802.1204v1[math.PR]9 Feb 2008. [11] El Karoui, N., Peng, S., and Quenez, M.C. Backward Stochastic Differential Equation in

Fi-nance.Mathematical Finance. 7(1) , 1-71(1997). ) MR1434407

[12] Endre Pap, Regular Null-Additive Monotone Set Functions. Uni.u Novom Sadu Zb. Rad. Prirod.-Mat.Fak. Ser. Mat. Fak. Ser. Mat.25,2, 93-101(1995). MR1413960

[13] Espen R. Jakobsen. Continuous Dependence Estimate for Viscosity Solutions of Fully Degener-ate Parabolic Equations.Journal of Differential Equations183, 497-525(2002). MR1919788 [14] Harrison, M. and Kreps, D. Martingales and Arbitrage in Multi-period Securities Markets.

Jour-nal of Economics Theory20, 381-408(1979). MR0540823

[15] Hull, J.C., and White, A. The Pricing of Options with Stochastic Volatility, Journal of Finance 42, 211-300(1987).

[16] James D. Stein, JR. Uniform Absolute Continuity in Spaces of Set Functions.Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, Vol. 51, No.1, August 1975. MR0440012

[17] Krylov, N.V.Controlled Diffusion Processes, 173-192. Springer-Verlag(1980). MR0601776 [18] Li, J. Order Continuity of Monotone Set Function and Convergence of Measurable Function

Sequence.Applied Mathematics and Computation, Vol.135, 211-218(2003). MR1937247 [19] Lyons, T.J. Uncertain Volatility and the Risk-Free Synthesis of Derivatives.Appl. Mathe. Finance

2, 117-133(1995).

[20] Merton, R. The Theory of Rational Option Pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4, 141-178(1973). MR0496534

[21] Mete Soner, H., Touzi Nizar, and Zhang JF. Martigale Representation Theorem for the G Ex-pectation. arXiv:1001.3802v1[math.PR]21 Jan 2010.


(6)

[22] Murofushi, T., Uchino, K., and Asahina, S. Conditions for Egoroff’s Theorem in Non-Additive Measure Theory,Fuzzy Sets and Systems,Vol.146, 135-146(2004). MR2074207

[23] Peng, S. G-expectation, G-Brownian Motion and Related Stochastic Calculus of Ito’s type (2006). http://arxiv.org/PS_cache/math/pdf/0601/0601035v2.pdf MR2397805

[24] Peng, S. G-Brownian Motion and Dynamic Risk Measure under Volatility Uncertainty (2007). http://arxiv.org/PS_cache/arxiv/pdf/0711/0711.2834v1.pdf . MR2397805

[25] Peng, S. A New Central Limit Theorem under Sublinear Expectations (2008). http://arxiv.org /PS_cache/arxiv/pdf/0803/0803.2656v1.pdf

[26] Song, JJ. On a Generalization of Convergence Theorems in Non-Additive Measure Theory, Chiba University Doctor’s Theisis. 2005.

[27] Stein, E., and Stein, J. Stock Price Distributions with Stochastic Volatility: An Analytic Ap-proach.Review of Financial Studies4, 727-752(1991).

[28] Wang, L. On the Regularity of Fully Nonlinear Parabolic Equations: II.Comm. Pure Appl. Math. 45, 141-178(1992). MR1139064

[29] Xu, J., and Zhang, B. Martingale Characterization of G Brownian Motion.Stochastic Processes and their Applications,119, 232-248(2009). MR2485026


Dokumen yang terkait

AN ALIS IS YU RID IS PUT USAN BE B AS DAL AM P E RKAR A TIND AK P IDA NA P E NY E RTA AN M E L AK U K A N P R AK T IK K E DO K T E RA N YA NG M E N G A K IB ATK AN M ATINYA P AS IE N ( PUT USA N N O MOR: 9 0/PID.B /2011/ PN.MD O)

0 82 16

ANALISIS FAKTOR YANGMEMPENGARUHI FERTILITAS PASANGAN USIA SUBUR DI DESA SEMBORO KECAMATAN SEMBORO KABUPATEN JEMBER TAHUN 2011

2 53 20

EFEKTIVITAS PENDIDIKAN KESEHATAN TENTANG PERTOLONGAN PERTAMA PADA KECELAKAAN (P3K) TERHADAP SIKAP MASYARAKAT DALAM PENANGANAN KORBAN KECELAKAAN LALU LINTAS (Studi Di Wilayah RT 05 RW 04 Kelurahan Sukun Kota Malang)

45 393 31

FAKTOR – FAKTOR YANG MEMPENGARUHI PENYERAPAN TENAGA KERJA INDUSTRI PENGOLAHAN BESAR DAN MENENGAH PADA TINGKAT KABUPATEN / KOTA DI JAWA TIMUR TAHUN 2006 - 2011

1 35 26

A DISCOURSE ANALYSIS ON “SPA: REGAIN BALANCE OF YOUR INNER AND OUTER BEAUTY” IN THE JAKARTA POST ON 4 MARCH 2011

9 161 13

Pengaruh kualitas aktiva produktif dan non performing financing terhadap return on asset perbankan syariah (Studi Pada 3 Bank Umum Syariah Tahun 2011 – 2014)

6 101 0

Pengaruh pemahaman fiqh muamalat mahasiswa terhadap keputusan membeli produk fashion palsu (study pada mahasiswa angkatan 2011 & 2012 prodi muamalat fakultas syariah dan hukum UIN Syarif Hidayatullah Jakarta)

0 22 0

Pendidikan Agama Islam Untuk Kelas 3 SD Kelas 3 Suyanto Suyoto 2011

4 108 178

ANALISIS NOTA KESEPAHAMAN ANTARA BANK INDONESIA, POLRI, DAN KEJAKSAAN REPUBLIK INDONESIA TAHUN 2011 SEBAGAI MEKANISME PERCEPATAN PENANGANAN TINDAK PIDANA PERBANKAN KHUSUSNYA BANK INDONESIA SEBAGAI PIHAK PELAPOR

1 17 40

KOORDINASI OTORITAS JASA KEUANGAN (OJK) DENGAN LEMBAGA PENJAMIN SIMPANAN (LPS) DAN BANK INDONESIA (BI) DALAM UPAYA PENANGANAN BANK BERMASALAH BERDASARKAN UNDANG-UNDANG RI NOMOR 21 TAHUN 2011 TENTANG OTORITAS JASA KEUANGAN

3 32 52