General bounds getdoc8cb2. 256KB Jun 04 2011 12:04:39 AM

and Theorem 3. The bound of Theorem 2 involves v = P k kE[X 2 k |F k k −1 ]k ∞ , and a remainder term involving conditional expectations kE[X k |F k i ]k ∞ . This is slightly unsatisfactory since it is known that the key quantity in the case of a martingale is the quadratic variation 〈X 〉 = P n k=1 E[X 2 k |F k −1 ], and in most cases effective bounds will actually involve k〈X 〉k ∞ , which is smaller than v. This is corrected in Theorem 1, where we give a result which generalizes what is known from martingale theory and improves on classical papers concerned with mixing [6]. However, inspection of the bounds shows that this improvement is really effective only if the conditional expectations |E[X k |F k i ]| are significantly smaller than |X k |; if not, the only way to improve accuracy is to use the second order approach of Section 3 briefly discussed below. Second order results. By this terminology, we mean the following fact: the Hoeffding inequality Equation 1 with ρ = 0 for instance is obtained from the exponential inequality E[e tS ] ≤ e t 2 P i b 2 i 8 . 7 One obvious drawback of this upper bound is that when t tends to 0, it does not look like 1+t 2 E[S 2 ]. One would rather expect something like E[e tS ] ≤ e t 2 E[S 2 ]2+C t 3 8 which has more interesting scaling properties; this approach would hopefully lead to significant improvements in a moderate deviation domain; this is what has been done in [5], but there S is an arbitrary function of independent variables, or of a Markov chain. In order to get closer, like in Equation 34 and 41 below, we have to pay with higher order extra terms: the remainder terms will not only contain conditional expectations E[X k |F k i ] but also conditional covariances; this will force us to consider for each pair of indices i, j another reordering of the sequence which corresponds to increasing dependence with the pair X i , X j , and to introduce σ-fields H i j k ; we postpone details to Section 3. In this context we shall give exponential inequalities and Gaussian approximation; we give in partic- ular a bound for |E[hX ]− E[hN]| where h is any function of n variables with all third derivatives bounded and N is a Gaussian random variable with same covariance matrix as X . The paper is organized as follows. The two forthcoming sections deal with first order and second or- der exponential inequalities. A classical use of the exponential inequalities leads to Theorem 4 which generalizes the Bernstein and Hoeffding inequalities. An application to concentration inequalities and triangle counts is given in Section 2.2. Section 3 is concerned with the second order approach, with applications to bounded difference inequalities and triangle counts. In Section 4 we give some estimates under mixing assumptions. 2 First order approach

2.1 General bounds

This section is devoted to bounds for the Laplace transform of S. The corresponding deviation probabilities will be obtained in Section 2.2.1 through classical arguments. 755 In Theorem 1 we present bounds which generalize known results concerning martingales. Since they only use the linear sequence of σ-fields F k , they are essentially interesting for time series. In Theorem 2 we give a Hoeffding bound which is valid in both cases time series and random fields, and Theorem 3 gives a Bennett bound for random fields which does not exactly generalizes 9 because the quadratic variation 〈X 〉 is changed into the more drastic upper bound v. The applicability of the following theorem depends on the way one can bound the quadratic varia- tions involved. In the forthcoming examples, we shall consider only Equation 9 through a bound on k〈X 〉k ∞ ; however Equations 10 and 11 have the advantage of not involving m. Theorem 1. We are in the setting described in the introduction, with the filtration defined by 5. The variables X k are centered. We define m = sup 1 ≤k≤n ess sup X k [X ] = n X k=1 X 2 k 〈X 〉 = n X k=1 E[X 2 k |F k −1 ] [X + ] = n X k=1 X k 2 + 〈X − 〉 = n X k=1 E[X k 2 − |F k −1 ] q = n X k=1 k −1 X i=1 kX i k ∞ kE[X k |F i ]k ∞ where the notation x 2 + resp. x 2 − stands for x 2 1 x resp. x 2 1 x . Then E exp S − 〈X 〉 m 2 e m − m − 1 ≤ e 4q 9 E exp S − 1 2 [X + ] − 1 2 〈X − 〉 ≤ e 4q 10 E exp S − 1 6 [X ] − 1 3 〈X 〉 ≤ e 4q . 11 R EMARK . In the martingale case q = 0. We recommend [1] for an account on recent work concerning exponential inequalities for martingales. Proof. Consider a pair of functions θ x and ψx such that ψ ≥ 0, e x −θ x ≤ 1 + x + ψx. 12 756 These functions are meant to be Ox 2 in the neighborhood of 0. Three examples of such functions are θ x = 0, ψx = e x − x − 1 θ x = ζx + , ψx = ζx − , ζx = e −x + x − 1 θ x = x 2 6 , ψx = x 2 3 . Inequality 12 for these functions is proved in Proposition 12 of the Appendix. Set T k = k X i=1 X i − θ X i − log1 + ξ i , where ξ i = E[ψX i |F i −1 ]. Then E[e T n ] = E[e X n −θ X n 1 + ξ n −1 e T n −1 ] ≤ E[1 + X n + ψX n 1 + ξ n −1 e T n −1 ] = E[X n 1 + ξ n −1 e T n −1 ] + E[e T n −1 ] = E[X n 1 + ξ n −1 − 1e T n −1 ] + E n −1 X i=1 X n e T i − e T i −1 + E[e T n −1 ] = r 1 + r 2 + E[e T n −1 ]. In the martingale case, the first two terms are zero; here we have r 1 = E[E[X n |F n −1 ]e T n −1 ξ n 1 + ξ n ] ≤ E[|E[X n |F n −1 ]|e T n −1 ]kψX n k ∞ ∧ 1. The above defined function ψ is convex with ψ0 = 0, ψ−1 ≤ 1 and ψ1 ≤ 1. Hence |ψx|∧1 ≤ |x| and therefore r 1 ≤ kX n k ∞ kE[X n |F n −1 ]k ∞ E[e T n −1 ]. Let ∆ i = T i − T i −1 ; the second remainder is bounded as follows: r 2 = E n −1 X i=1 X n tanh∆ i 2e T i + e T i −1 ≤ E n −1 X i=1 |E[X n |F i ]∆ i |e T i + e T i −1 2 ≤ n −1 X i=1 kE[X n |F i ]∆ i k ∞ sup j ≤n−1 E[e T j ]. Equation 53 of the Appendix implies that | tanh∆ i | ≤ 3kX i k ∞ , hence r 2 ≤ 3ρ n sup i ≤n−1 E[e T i ], ρ n = n −1 X i=1 kX i k ∞ kE[X n |F i ]k ∞ . 757 Finally E[e T n ] ≤ 1 + 4ρ n sup i ≤n−1 E[e T i ] ≤ exp4ρ n sup i ≤n−1 E[e T i ] and we get by induction that sup i ≤k E[e T i ] ≤ exp4 k X i=1 ρ i . In particular E   exp n X i=1 X i − θ X i − log1 + E[ψX i |F i −1 ]   ≤ exp4q hence E[exp { n X i=1 X i − θ X i − E[ψX i |F i −1 ]}] ≤ exp4q. This leads to the three bounds by using the three pairs of functions and by noticing that for m ≥ 0 and x ≤ m ϕx ≤ ϕm, ϕx = e x − x − 1 x 2 13 which is a consequence of L’Hospital’s rule for monotonicity [ ? ], and that for x ≥ 0 ζx ≤ x 2 2 since the function x 2 2 − ζx has a non-negative derivative. Theorem 2. Assume that we are in the setting described in the introduction, with a family of σ-fields satisfying 6. The variables X k are centered. We define now q as q = n X k=1 k −1 X i=1 kX k i k ∞ kE[X k |F k i ]k ∞ this is consistent with the definition in Theorem 1. If the variables are lower and upper bounded with probability one: a i ≤ X i ≤ a i + b i 14 the following inequality holds E   exp S − 1 8 X i b 2 i   ≤ e 8q . 15 In the martingale case F k i = F i and E[X i |F i −1 ] = 0 for all i and k, this inequality remains true if we allow a i and b i to be an F i −1 -measurable random variables. 758 Proof. We assume first that a i and b i are deterministic. We start, as in the proof of the Hoeffding inequality, with the following inequality based on the majoration of the exponential function by the chord over the curve on [a, a + b]: e x ≤ a + be a − ae a+b b + x e a+b − e a b , a ≤ x ≤ a + b. e c e x a a + b x c It is well known that the first term of the right hand side, e c on the figure, is smaller than expb 2 8 independently of a this a key step for proving the Hoeffding inequality, see for instance Appendix B of [ ? ]. On the other hand, it is clear that c ≤ a + b see the figure or bound e a with e a+b in the expression of e c . Hence, if we define c i and d i with the equations c i = min b 2 i 8 , a i + b i , d i = e a i e b i − 1 b i we have e x ≤ e c i + d i x, a i ≤ x ≤ a i + b i . Now let the random variables T j and T k j be defined as T k = k X i=1 X i − c i , T k j = j X i=1 X k i − c k i where c k i i ≤k is the corresponding reordering of the sequence c i i ≤k . We obtain E[e T n ] = E[e X n e T n −1 −c n ] ≤ E[e c n + d n X n e T n −1 −c n ] In the martingale case, the term involving d n vanishes and this equation gives immediately the result. We assume now that we are not necessarily in this case but a i and b i are deterministic. We can assume in addition, without loss of generality, that a i and b i are chosen so that 14 is tight. Notice that in this case we also have a i ≤ 0 ≤ a i + b i since E[X i ] = 0. The previous equation implies E[e T n ] ≤ d n e −c n E[X n e T n −1 ] + E[e T n −1 ] = d n e −c n E n −1 X i=1 X n e T n i − e T n i −1 + E[e T n −1 ] = d n e −c n r 2 + E[e T n −1 ]. 16 759 Let ∆ i = T n i − T n i −1 = X n i − c n i ; bounding r 2 as in the proof of Theorem 1 we get r 2 = E n −1 X i=1 X n tanh∆ i 2e T n i + e T n i −1 ≤ E n −1 X i=1 |E[X n |F n i ]∆ i |e T n i + e T n i −1 2 ≤ n −1 X i=1 kE[X n |F n i ]∆ i k ∞ sup j ≤n−1 E[e T n j ] and since |∆ i | ≤ maxa n i + b n i − c n i , c n i − a n i ≤ b n i ≤ 2kX n i k ∞ b n i is the difference between the essential supremum and the essential infimum we get that r 2 ≤ 2ρ n sup i ≤n−1 E[e T n i ], with ρ n = n −1 X i=1 kX n i k ∞ kE[X n |F n i ]k ∞ . On the other hand since a i ≤ 0 the Equation 55 in Propostion 13 of the Appendix leads to d n e −c n ≤ 4 and 16 becomes finally E[e T n ] ≤ 1 + 8ρ n sup i ≤n−1 E[e T n i ] ≤ e 8 ρ n sup i ≤n−1 E[e T n i ]. For any sequence α ∈ {0, 1} n set T k α = k X i=1 α i X i − c i . The bound we obtained is still obviously valid for T n α since the replacement of X i with α i X i does not increases ρ n , hence sup α E[e T n α ] ≤ e 8 ρ n sup α sup i ≤n−1 E[e T n i α ] = e 8 ρ n sup α E[e T n −1 α ] and we get E[e T n ] ≤ exp 8 n X i=1 ρ i . We obtain 15 by using that c i ≤ b 2 i 8 in the expression of T n . Theorem 3. Assume that we are in the setting described in the introduction, with a family of σ-fields satifying 6. The variables X k are centered. We define v = n X k=1 kE[X 2 k |X k −1 , . . . X 1 ]k ∞ , m as in Theorem 1, and q as in Theorem 2. Then for any t E[e S ] ≤ exp  v m 2 e m − m − 1 + q ‹ . 17 760 Proof. We set S i = X n 1 + X n 2 + · · · + X n i , i ≤ n and S = 0. Equation 13 implies that e X n ≤ 1 + X n + X 2 n ϕm hence E[e S ] ≤ E[1 + X n + X 2 n ϕme S n −1 ] = E n −1 X i=1 X n e S i − e S i −1 + E[1 + X 2 n ϕme S n −1 ] = E n −1 X i=1 X n X n i tanhX n i 2 X n i e S i + e S i −1 + ϕmE[X 2 n e S n −1 ] + E[e S n −1 ] ≤ E n −1 X i=1 kE[X n |F n i ]X n i k ∞ e S n i + e S i −1 2 + ϕmE[E[X 2 n |F n n −1 ]e S n −1 ] + E[e S n −1 ] ≤ 1 + q n + ϕmv n sup i ≤n−1 E[e S i ] ≤ e q n +ϕmv n sup i ≤n−1 E[e S i ] where q n and v n are the terms corresponding to k = n in the definition of q and v. This proves the result by induction.

2.2 Applications

Dokumen yang terkait

AN ALIS IS YU RID IS PUT USAN BE B AS DAL AM P E RKAR A TIND AK P IDA NA P E NY E RTA AN M E L AK U K A N P R AK T IK K E DO K T E RA N YA NG M E N G A K IB ATK AN M ATINYA P AS IE N ( PUT USA N N O MOR: 9 0/PID.B /2011/ PN.MD O)

0 82 16

ANALISIS FAKTOR YANGMEMPENGARUHI FERTILITAS PASANGAN USIA SUBUR DI DESA SEMBORO KECAMATAN SEMBORO KABUPATEN JEMBER TAHUN 2011

2 53 20

EFEKTIVITAS PENDIDIKAN KESEHATAN TENTANG PERTOLONGAN PERTAMA PADA KECELAKAAN (P3K) TERHADAP SIKAP MASYARAKAT DALAM PENANGANAN KORBAN KECELAKAAN LALU LINTAS (Studi Di Wilayah RT 05 RW 04 Kelurahan Sukun Kota Malang)

45 393 31

FAKTOR – FAKTOR YANG MEMPENGARUHI PENYERAPAN TENAGA KERJA INDUSTRI PENGOLAHAN BESAR DAN MENENGAH PADA TINGKAT KABUPATEN / KOTA DI JAWA TIMUR TAHUN 2006 - 2011

1 35 26

A DISCOURSE ANALYSIS ON “SPA: REGAIN BALANCE OF YOUR INNER AND OUTER BEAUTY” IN THE JAKARTA POST ON 4 MARCH 2011

9 161 13

Pengaruh kualitas aktiva produktif dan non performing financing terhadap return on asset perbankan syariah (Studi Pada 3 Bank Umum Syariah Tahun 2011 – 2014)

6 101 0

Pengaruh pemahaman fiqh muamalat mahasiswa terhadap keputusan membeli produk fashion palsu (study pada mahasiswa angkatan 2011 & 2012 prodi muamalat fakultas syariah dan hukum UIN Syarif Hidayatullah Jakarta)

0 22 0

Pendidikan Agama Islam Untuk Kelas 3 SD Kelas 3 Suyanto Suyoto 2011

4 108 178

ANALISIS NOTA KESEPAHAMAN ANTARA BANK INDONESIA, POLRI, DAN KEJAKSAAN REPUBLIK INDONESIA TAHUN 2011 SEBAGAI MEKANISME PERCEPATAN PENANGANAN TINDAK PIDANA PERBANKAN KHUSUSNYA BANK INDONESIA SEBAGAI PIHAK PELAPOR

1 17 40

KOORDINASI OTORITAS JASA KEUANGAN (OJK) DENGAN LEMBAGA PENJAMIN SIMPANAN (LPS) DAN BANK INDONESIA (BI) DALAM UPAYA PENANGANAN BANK BERMASALAH BERDASARKAN UNDANG-UNDANG RI NOMOR 21 TAHUN 2011 TENTANG OTORITAS JASA KEUANGAN

3 32 52