Payment by Banknotes References

270 = 2, there exists a double coincidence of wants between and . Further, given = , the number of is the same as that of . Therefore, = holds. That is, all merchants in region A and B can obtain all the goods they want at t = 2. Consequently, in this situation the utility of all merchants is u = u = u b . 3 Given = = , all demands for b and b equal one and the markets for and clear. 2 Case 2: = = As in the previous case, the number of is again the same as the number of . Therefore, the exchange rate of for is = . Therefore, the utility of all merchants is u = u = u b . 3 Case 3: = , = In this case, is double that of . Therefore, the exchange rate of for is = . Thus, can receive in return for giving to so that they can obtain two units of at t = 2. Therefore, their utility level is u ≡ � . However, given = , can obtain only half a unit of such that its utility is u ≡ u b . Note that the demand for is the sum of the demands by who require one unit of and the demands by who require two units of . As the number of is − and the number of is , the total demand for is − + . In this case, = and = , therefore the demand for is one. All demands are satisfied. In the same way, the demand for is − + α = so that the demand for also clears. 4 Case 4: = , = This is the opposite to the previous case. Accordingly, receives and its utility is u . And receives and its utility is u . In this case, as in the previous case, the markets for both and clear. As a result, the expected utility of the merchant in region A at t = 0 [� ] is [� ] = � + � + { � + � } + { � + � } = � + 6 � + � 1 The first and second terms on the right-hand side of 1 denote the expected utility level for cases 1 and 2. The third term denotes the expected utility level of case 3 in which a merchant in region A wants to consume the good of bank A and B with a probability of 13 and 23, respectively. From this equation, it is obvious that in the situation where only banknotes circulate, the consumption level of the merchant fluctuates. 4 This is because, from cases 3 and 4, the exchange rate of for depends on the realization of and . Given the merchant is risk averse, the fluctuation in consumption decreases the merchant’s expected utility.

4. Fiat Money

Next, consider the situation where fiat money can circulate in the economy. To consider this 3 Suppose that if the merchant receives a good which the merchant does not value i.e., receives or receives , the utility level of the merchant is then zero. We also assume that the utility function is identical across all merchants. 4 See the third and fourth terms in 1. 271 situation, we introduce a central bank into the model. The role of the central bank is to provide fiat money to the banks at t = . The central bank can do this because the central bank can evaluate the products of both banks. In other words, if both banks cannot repay the fiat money to the central bank at t = 2, the central bank is able to seize all of the banks products. For this reason, the central bank provides only one unit of fiat money at t = 0 to both banks. In this situation, and contrary to the previous case, the merchants who want to consume the products of banks in a different region i.e., M and M do not need to exchange their banknotes for each other. Instead, they demand the bank in the same region to transfer the banknote to the bank in the different region. As in the previous section, we categorize this situation into four categories. 1 Case 1: = = and Case 2: = = In this case, consumers in region A C pay their endowment good to B and are repaid one unit of fiat money at t = 0. At t = 1, a fraction − of merchants in region A M find that they will want to consume the product produced by B . On the other hand, a fraction of merchants find that they will want to consume the product produced by B at t = 2. Contrary to the previous case, these transactions have taken place with fiat money and then merchants can receive the good produced by a bank in a different region. Since = , the demands for b and b are 1 so that the markets for b and b clear and thus all merchants receive the goods they want. 2 Case 3: = , = Next, consider the case where = and = . In this case, the demand for b is the sum of the demands by M and the demand by M . Contrary to the previous case, both M and M hold one unit of fiat money. Since the number of M is − and the number of M is , the total demand for b is − + = so that both merchants can receive one unit of b and thus their utility becomes u b . In this case, the bank in region A can aquire 23 units of fiat money but 13 units of b remain unsold. Although the bank should repay one unit of fiat money to the central bank at t=2, it can complete the payment by repaying 23 units of fiat money and giving 13 units of b to the central bank. The reason why this transaction can be settled is that we assume that the central bank can seize all of the banks products. On the other hand, since the number of M is − and the number of M is , the total demand for b is + − = so that these merchants can receive 34 units of b . Therefore, their expected utility become u b . In this case, the bank in region B can acquires 43 units of fiat money so that it can repay one unit of fiat money to the central bank at t=2 and 13 units of fiat money become useless at the end of t=2. As a result, the expected utility of the merchant in region A at t = 0: E [u ] is